Appendix E
Details of the Economic Model
Introduction
This appendix describes in more technical
detail the economic model and data underlying the estimates in chapter 3. The
appendix begins with a review of two studies which also examine some aspects of
Massachusetts’s recent goals and commitments that are the focus of this report.
The rest of the appendix is divided into four broad sections, which discuss
model inputs, model outputs, data sources, and additional results.
The section on model inputs provides more
specifics about the calculation of model inputs, including details of how the
load shares of the goals and commitments and of hydroelectricity are
calculated; how the model calculates the way electricity sourcing shifts to
meet the clean and renewable standards; how the compliance credits are modeled;
and some background information on the five scenarios taken from the U.S.
Energy Information Administration’s (EIA) Annual Energy Outlook (AEO).
The model outputs section supplies
additional details on the calculations of the key model results: effects on the
price of wholesale generation, effects on the costs to Massachusetts consumers,
effects on the costs to New England consumers, and effects on Massachusetts
emissions.
The data sources section provides details
about the sources for the data in the model, including more detail on
calculations used throughout.
The additional results section presents
results to supplement the analysis in chapter 3. First, it reports additional
estimates of the greenhouse gas emissions, giving model projections for the
four alternative scenarios. Then, it presents a sensitivity analysis of the
modeling assumptions outlined in table 3.2. These three sensitivity analyses
focus on (1) changing the marginal resource used to satisfy renewable portfolio
standard (RPS) and clean energy standard (CES) demand; (2) changing how much
access Massachusetts has to clean energy imports; and (3) changing the
assumption about the number of residential and commercial customers.
As was the case in chapter 3, for this
appendix, “renewable” refers specifically to resources that qualify for
Massachusetts’s RPS commitment and “clean” refers to resources that qualify for
Massachusetts’s CES commitment, unless otherwise specified.
Related Studies of Massachusetts’s Recent Goals and Commitments
Two other studies have considered the
potential effects of certain aspects of Massachusetts’s renewable and clean
energy commitments on ratepayers and greenhouse gas emissions in the past five
years. The first (“Massachusetts Energy study”) was prepared by Synapse Energy
Economics and Sustainable Energy Advantage at the request of Northeast Clean
Energy Council Institute and Massachusetts Energy Consumers Alliance. Published
in May 2017, the study compares a baseline case to potential modifications to Massachusetts’s
and Connecticut’s RPS commitments. For Massachusetts, the baseline case
includes the 2016 Act to Promote Energy Diversity, which committed
Massachusetts to acquiring long-term contracts for both offshore wind and for
clean energy;[1]
the Global Warming Solutions Act (GWSA) emissions commitments, which set
economy-wide targets to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 80 percent of their
1990 levels by 2050; and Massachusetts’s prior commitment to increasing its RPS
by 1 percentage points per year through 2050. The study then considers, among
other things, the effect of altering Massachusetts’s and Connecticut’s RPS
commitments three ways: (1) an increase of 2 percentage points per year in
Massachusetts’s RPS; (2) an increase of 2 percentage points per year in
Massachusetts’s RPS and an increase of 1.5 percentage points per year of
Connecticut’s RPS; and (3) an increase of 3 percentage points per year in
Massachusetts’s RPS and an increase of 1.5 percentage points per year in
Connecticut’s RPS.[2]
The second study (“Massachusetts Senate
study”), published in June 2018, was prepared by the Applied Economics Clinic
and Sustainable Energy Advantage at the request of the Massachusetts Senate
Committee on Global Warming and Climate Change. This study analyzes the effect
of provisions proposed in drafts of the 2018 Act to Promote Clean Energy: (1)
an acceleration to Massachusetts’s RPS from 1 percentage point per year to 3
percentage points per year, (2) a commitment to building 5,000 megawatts of
offshore wind by 2035, (3) reaching 1,766 MW of battery storage in-state by
2025, and (4) removing the cap on net metering of electricity (the selling of
electricity back to the grid) from small solar installations.[3]
The 2018 Act ultimately included an acceleration of 2 percentage points per
year, rather than the 3 percent acceleration examined in this study.
Additionally, the 2018 Act set a goal for potential offshore wind procurement
at an additional 1,600 megawatts, instead of the full 5,000 megawatts modeled in
the report.[4]
Both the 2017 Massachusetts Energy and
2018 Massachusetts Senate reports are built using multiple proprietary models
developed by private organizations: the EnCompass
model, which models electricity sector capacity buildout and generation dispatch,
and the Renewable Energy Market Outlook model, which models renewable energy
buildout and forecasts REC prices. These are large electricity system models
that simulate the effect of renewable energy sourcing commitments on a variety
of economic indicators, including the impact on greenhouse gas emissions and on
retail electricity rates. Their models project the effects of the respective
commitments out to 2030 under several alternative scenarios to reflect
uncertainty over future market conditions.
The 2017 Massachusetts Energy study found
that increasing the RPS in Massachusetts to 2 percentage points per year would
result in an increase in in-region renewable electricity capacity of between
300 and 1,100 megawatts (MW).[5]
The study also found that increasing Massachusetts’s RPS commitment to 2
percentage points per year is projected to reduce wholesale electricity prices
by an average 0.3 percent per year between 2025 and 2030.[6] As
for retail prices, the study found an additional monthly cost to consumers of
between $0.10 and $0.20 from 2018 to 2030 when the RPS was increased to 2
percentage points per year.[7] This study also projected a baseline
decrease in electricity sector emissions by 2030 of 60 percent over 1990
levels, while the increase in Massachusetts’s RPS to 2 percentage points
per year would result in a reduction in emissions of 62 percent of the 1990
levels.[8]
The 2018 Massachusetts Senate study, by
contrast, found that the commitments modeled would result in additional
renewable generation capacity buildout of approximately 1,500 MW in
Massachusetts.[9]
This study predicted a reduction in emissions due to the commitments equal to
0.6 million metric tons of greenhouse gas emissions.[10]
Finally, the study predicted an increase in Massachusetts’s average household
electricity bills of 44 cents per month (or 0.25 cents per kWh) for the first
three years of the forecast, with prices falling below their initial value
thereafter. On average, this would result in a reduction of consumer bills by
about 1.5 percent over the 2018 to 2030 window.[11]
Model Inputs
Calculation of Load Shares for Goals and Commitments,
Hydroelectricity
The Commission’s model focuses on the
effects of Massachusetts’s updated Class I renewable portfolio standards.[12]
These standards do not mandate that a certain share of electricity generation
in Massachusetts or New England come from clean or renewable sources.[13]
Rather, they require that Massachusetts utilities purchase or earn enough
compliance credits to cover a mandated share of the electricity load that they
serve. Massachusetts’s RPS can be satisfied by renewable resources, including
wind and solar, located in New England or interconnected regions. The Class I
RPS commitment increases to 55 percent of Massachusetts’s load by 2050.
Massachusetts’s CES commitment is higher, rising to 80 percent of Massachusetts
load by 2050. It can be satisfied by hydroelectric generation (built after
2010) or nuclear generation (built after 2010), as well as by any Class I
renewable resources.
In the tables and formulas below, So represents the initial (or “old”) RPS share of
Massachusetts’s load, Su represents the
updated RPS share, and Sc represents the CES share. In each year, Sc
< Su < Sc. Table E.1
reports the shares for 2030, 2035, 2040, 2045, and 2050.[14]
Table
E.1
Renewable and clean energy requirements (as a percentage of total load)
Share |
2030 |
2035 |
2040 |
2045 |
2050 |
So |
25 |
30 |
35 |
40 |
45 |
Su |
35 |
40 |
45 |
50 |
55 |
Sc |
40 |
50 |
60 |
70 |
80 |
Sc – Su |
5 |
10 |
15 |
20 |
25 |
Source: State of Massachusetts, “Program Summaries:
Summaries of all the Renewable and Alternative Energy Portfolio Standard
Programs,” (accessed September 16, 2020); “Clean Energy Standard,” 310 CMR 7.75 (2017),
509, 513–14; “Act to Advance Clean Energy (H4857),” 2018,; “Renewable Energy
Portfolio Standard for Retail Electricity Suppliers,” Mass. Gen. Laws ch. 25A, § 11 F.
As discussed in a footnote in the
“Massachusetts’s Recent Goals and Commitments” section of chapter 3, the
renewable and clean energy commitments modeled in this report generally apply
to investor-owned utilities, not municipally owned utilities. Municipally owned
utilities account for about 14.1 percent of Massachusetts’s total electricity
demand.[15]
Table E.2 reports Sh,
the share of non-municipally provided load supplied by hydroelectric power in
each year in the AEO Reference case, including imports from Canada and New York.
Given that the AEO does not break imports down by generation source, the share
of total imports coming from hydroelectric generation is calculated using
reported shares of hydroelectricity in New England imports available on the
NEPOOL (New England Power Pool) General Information System. The NEPOOL
information shows that for the most recent available data, 24.8 percent of
electricity imports from New York State and 96.0 percent of electricity imports
from Quebec were from hydroelectric generation.[16]
Hydroelectricity generated in New England is not counted in the calculation of Sh due to a simplifying assumption that all New
England hydroelectric facilities came online before 2011 and would not qualify
to fill Massachusetts’s CES commitments.
Table
E.2
Projected share from hydroelectric power, Reference case (as a percentage of
total load)
Share |
2019 |
2030 |
2035 |
2040 |
2045 |
2050 |
Sh |
16.2 |
14.6 |
14.0 |
14.3 |
14.2 |
14.2 |
Source: USITC calculations.
Note that although table E.2 shows a
decrease in the share of hydroelectric power (hydro) in total load over the
2019 to 2050 timeframe, the projected levels of hydro are relatively stable,
starting at 7.5 TWh in 2019, initially falling
slightly, and ending at 7.8 TWh in 2050.
Shift in the Electricity Sourcing to Meet the Standards
Since hydroelectric generation qualifies
for Massachusetts’s CES, hydroelectricity satisfies most, and in some years
all, of the gap between Su and Sc.
For the first two periods of the model, tables E.1 and E.2 show that the entire
commitment of Massachusetts’s CES above its RPS would be satisfied by imported
hydroelectricity, since Sh > Sc
– Su. The gap between Sh
and Sc – Su would be less than
1 percent in 2040 and would then rise to become closer to 5 and 10 percent in
2045 and 2050, respectively.
The model assumes that any difference
between Massachusetts’s CES and RPS commitment that is not satisfied by
hydroelectricity would be satisfied by building additional RPS-eligible
generation in New England. It is not likely that imports of hydroelectricity
would increase to fill this gap, since there are international transmission
constraints that would likely persist for decades into the future.[17]
Furthermore, building new nuclear or hydroelectric generation in New England is
not projected to be cost effective when compared to building renewables like
wind and solar.[18]
Tables E.3 and E.4 report the projected
generation mix in the New England region in the AEO 2020 Reference case as
supporting evidence for the argument that wind and solar, not hydroelectricity,
will meet the additional demand for clean energy. Electricity generation in AEO
projections is divided into two major categories: generation by the electric
power sector (table E.3), which is generation by utility-scale providers that
then distribute electricity to the end users, and generation by the end-use
sector (table E.4), which is generation by the end users themselves. For
generation in the electric power sector, the greatest growth is projected in
production from onshore and offshore wind, while hydroelectric power and other
renewable sources remain relatively constant. Growth in offshore wind is
projected to occur rapidly over the next 10 years and then level off. A similar
pattern is projected in onshore wind. For generation in the end-use sector,
most of the projected increase beyond 2030 is in solar generation, representing
on-site solar installations (including rooftop solar generation).[19]
The AEO projects that other renewable and clean energy sources will remain
relatively constant.
Table
E.3
Projected renewable generation mix in the electric power sector in the New
England region, Reference case (in terawatt-hours)
Type of generation |
2019 |
2030 |
2035 |
2040 |
2045 |
2050 |
All renewable
and clean |
10.6 |
43.3 |
45.1 |
45.5 |
45.6 |
48.0 |
Solar (photovoltaic) |
1.5 |
2.0 |
2.0 |
2.0 |
2.1 |
2.4 |
Offshore wind |
0.1 |
7.1 |
8.8 |
8.8 |
8.8 |
8.8 |
Onshore wind |
3.3 |
26.7 |
26.7 |
27.1 |
27.1 |
28.9 |
Wood and other biomass |
3.3 |
3.6 |
3.6 |
3.6 |
3.6 |
3.6 |
Municipal waste |
2.4 |
4.0 |
4.0 |
4.0 |
4.0 |
4.3 |
Source:
Compiled from AEO 2020,
Reference Case estimates.
Note: The AEO defines the electric power
industry as “stationary and mobile generating units that are connected to the
electric power grid and can generate electricity. The electric power industry
includes the ‘electric power sector’ (utility generators and independent power
producers) and industrial and commercial power generators, including
combined-heat-and-power producers, but excludes units at single-family
dwellings.” EIA, “Glossary” (accessed September 21, 2020).
Table
E.4
Projected renewable generation mix in the end-use sector in the New England
region, Reference case (in terawatt-hours)
Type of generation |
2019 |
2030 |
2035 |
2040 |
2045 |
2050 |
All renewable
and clean |
6.6 |
12.7 |
14.4 |
16.3 |
18.1 |
19.9 |
Solar (photovoltaic) |
4.9 |
10.8 |
12.5 |
14.4 |
16.1 |
17.9 |
Onshore wind |
0.1 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
0.1 |
Wood and other biomass |
1.4 |
1.4 |
1.5 |
1.5 |
1.6 |
1.6 |
Municipal waste |
0.2 |
0.2 |
0.2 |
0.2 |
0.2 |
0.2 |
Source:
Compiled from AEO 2020, Reference Case estimates.
Given the anticipated size of solar as a
generation resource and that solar and wind are the renewable resources which
require the smallest incentives in the projection periods, the model assumes that
solar will be the marginal resource meeting demand for new renewables.[20]
Modeling the Value of Compliance Credits
The renewable and clean
energy standards are designed to incentivize new energy production through
the payment of compliance credits. The value of these incentives depends
on how profitable new energy plants would be absent the credits. A
plant’s profitability per megawatt-hour (MWh) of electricity generated is the
difference between the average cost and average revenue over the full life
cycle of the plant.
Massachusetts’s
increased commitments only create compliance costs to the extent that they are
needed to incentivize additional generation to meet the standards. If average
revenue is less than average cost, the renewable or clean energy
credit (or more generally “compliance credit”) covers the difference in
order to make the investment in renewable or clean energy
resources profitable, and the commitments are “incentivizing” new
renewable or clean generation. If the standards are incentivizing, then the
value of compliance credits is greater than zero and Massachusetts utilities
pay the cost of the credits, which they then pass on to Massachusetts retail
electricity consumers. For the model scenarios and years where the standards
are not incentivizing, the value of the credits is zero. In these years the
commitments have no effect on generation or other market outcomes and no effect
on costs to consumers.
The model estimates the
future values of the credits based on the economic fundamentals
that underlie the profitability of new renewable generation. These
fundamentals suggest that credit values should incorporate future technological
innovations, revenue opportunities, and all other factors that determine
the profitability of new generation.
For any share of
renewables S, a new generation plant’s profits per MWh, π,
are equal to the difference between its average revenue, AR, and its average
cost, AC:
(E1)
Table E.5 provides the
AEO’s projections for average revenue and average cost for solar photovoltaic
(PV) generation for each of the model years.
Table
E.5
Average revenue and average cost of the marginal solar generation plant,
Reference case (in 2019 dollars per megawatt-hour)
Measure |
2030 |
2035 |
2040 |
2045 |
2050 |
AR |
33.70 |
33.11 |
35.30 |
34.79 |
33.69 |
AC |
37.56 |
35.34 |
33.40 |
31.75 |
30.48 |
AR minus AC |
-3.87 |
-2.23 |
1.94 |
3.03 |
3.21 |
Source: EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020: LACE (available from
EIA on request; accessed October 2, 2020); EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020:
LCOE (available from EIA on request; accessed October 2, 2020).
Although these estimates are generally
low, REC prices in Massachusetts have been declining since they reached a peak
in 2014.[21]
At their highest, Class I RECs reached around $65 per MWh in 2014. The average
monthly closing price of RECs for Class I renewables in Massachusetts was
listed as low as approximately $5 per MWh in the third quarter of 2018,
reaching around $20 per MWh in the second quarter of 2019.[22]
To account for diminishing profitability
of renewables as their market share increases, the model adjusts the estimate
of the profitability (in terms of 2019 dollars per MWh) of additional renewable
generation at different levels of renewables penetration, using the
profitability curve defined in equation (E2):
(E2)
where S1 and S2
represent any two shares of renewable generation in the market. If share S2
is greater than share S1, then π(S2)
will be less than π(S1). This curve is almost
flat when S2 is close to S1, decreasing S2 as
increases, and becomes very negative as S2 approaches one. This
diminishing profitability of new generation as renewable penetration increases
in a particular year reflects the likely exhaustion of the best revenue
opportunities and least-cost projects.
The model estimates the equilibrium value
of the credit (VOC) required to incentivize enough additional renewable and
clean generation to meet the updated standards in equilibrium, based on
equation (E3):
(E3)
The compliance credit
represents an equilibrium outcome: if the value of the credit were smaller, the
standards would not be met; if the value of the credit were larger, excess
investments would drive down the value of the credit.
The model defines VOC0 as the
value of compliance credits under the initial RPS, and VOC1 as the
value of compliance credits under Massachusetts’s updated RPS and its CES.
These are not values at different points in time; they
are values at the same point in time for different levels of electricity
sourcing coming from renewables, so it is always the case that VOC1
is greater than or equal to VOC0. Starting from π(Su), the profitability projection from the AEO,
and defining Sx = MAX[0,
Sc – Su – Sh],
the profitability measures at the updated and initial RPS are given in
equations (E4) and (E5):
(E4)
(E5)
If Sh
> Sc – Su (no additional
renewable sources are required beyond those that meet the updated RPS), then
VOC1 can be calculated as the difference between average revenue and
average cost of the marginal renewable source, equal to MAX[0, – π(Su)]. This is the case in 2030 and 2035 for all
five AEO cases. If Sh < Sc –
Su (additional renewable sources are
required beyond those that meet the updated RPS), then there is an upward
adjustment in VOC1 as the profitability of the marginal renewable
resource falls. This is the case in the illustrative example provided in figure
E.1, which shows that VOC1 is found by a rightward movement along
the diminishing profitability curve from π(Su)
for 2050 for the AEO High Renewables Cost case as new renewable generation
becomes less profitable.
Figure E.1 provides an illustration of
the relationship between VOC0, equal to – π(S0),
and VOC1, equal to – π(S1), when Sh < Sc – Su
using the profitability curve for the year 2050 in the High Renewables Cost
case of the model. The figure shows that at the red point, labeled π(Su), the difference between AR and AC generated
by the AEO’s general equilibrium model is approximately −$7.63 per MWh of
generation. The numbers used for the value of the credits in the Commission’s
modeling, however, are the points labeled VOC0, the value of the
credit with the old RPS commitment in place, and VOC1, the value of
the credit with the updated RPS and the new CES in place. These values are
approximately $7.45 per MWh for the old commitment levels and $8.08 per MWh for
the new commitment levels, resulting in an additional credit of $0.63 per MWh.
The increased saturation of renewable and clean energy to meet the higher
commitments results in lower profitability per MWh, driving up the required credit
size to incentivize new renewable generation.
Source: USITC calculations.
Note: Underlying data for this figure can be found in appendix table G.41.
The model assumes that the residual of
Massachusetts’s CES over its updated RPS and imported hydroelectricity is met
by new renewable generation in New England, rather than clean nonrenewables. This is a reasonable assumption, because (1)
large nuclear facilities would take decades to permit and construct and high
construction costs, and (2) this report is not considering how additional
transmission from Canada to Massachusetts would affect Massachusetts’s ability
to meet its commitments.[23]
Given this assumption, the value of the credit will be the same for both
renewable and clean sources, as the model equalizes the return to new renewable
generation being used to fill either the RPS or CES commitment. However, if
adding hydroelectric power becomes a less expensive way to meet the residual of
Massachusetts’s CES over its updated RPS, then the model estimates may
overstate the effects of Massachusetts’s CES on compliance costs.
For context, the estimated share of
Massachusetts’s CES commitments met by additional renewables is given in table
E.6. The table only reports shares in 2040, 2045, and 2050; for all earlier
years of the model there is enough imported hydroelectricity to satisfy the
entirety of the difference between Massachusetts’s CES and RPS commitments.
Table
E.6
Additional renewable generation necessary to meet CES commitment (as a
percentage of total Massachusetts load)
Year |
CES minus RPS
share |
Reference case |
High
Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables
Cost case |
High Oil and
Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and
Gas Supply case |
2040 |
15.0 |
0.7 |
0.4 |
0.1 |
0.0 |
0.0 |
2045 |
20.0 |
5.8 |
5.1 |
5.1 |
3.1 |
4.0 |
2050 |
25.0 |
10.8 |
10.9 |
10.2 |
9.5 |
10.0 |
Source: USITC calculations.
Background on AEO Scenarios
As mentioned in chapter 3, the AEO uses a
comprehensive general equilibrium model of the U.S. economy to build
projections for the energy sector through 2050. To account for the uncertainty
of long-term projections, the AEO includes several alternative scenarios. The
modeling makes use of data from five of the AEO’s cases: the
Reference case, the High Renewables Cost case, the Low Renewables Cost case,
the High Oil and Gas Supply case, and the Low Oil and Gas Supply case. Due to
the uncertainty inherent in developing a model with projections 30 years into
the future, these cases provide insights for several possible states of the
world over the next three decades.
The Reference case represents the EIA’s
“best assessment of how the U.S. and world energy markets will operate through
2050, based on key assumptions intended to provide a base for exploring
long-term trends.”[24]
The alternative cases then present specific adjustments to allow for potential
departures from the Reference case.
First, consider the High and Low
Renewables Cost cases. Recall that in table 3.2, in the High Renewables Cost
case, overnight capital cost for renewables is assumed to remain at 2019
levels, where overnight capital cost is a hypothetical measure equal to the
cost of building a new power plant, assuming no interest accrues during the
process.[25]
For the Low Renewables Cost Case, the model assumes that overnight capital
cost, operating and maintenance costs, and fuel costs (where applicable) for
renewables fall 40 percent lower than the Reference case equivalents by 2050.[26]
From the AEO’s 2020 data release, figure E.2 shows how these two cases change
the forecast capital costs associated with solar photovoltaic (PV), wind, and
combined-cycle natural gas generation.
Figure
E.2 Overnight installed capital cost in the
United States by technology, Reference and alternative Renewables Cost
scenarios (in 2019 dollars per kilowatt)
Source: EIA, AEO2020 Full Report, January 29, 2020, 21.
Note: Underlying data for this figure can be found in appendix
tables G.42, G.43, and G.44.
The AEO’s Reference case depicts a higher
overnight capital cost for wind for almost the entirety of the forecast window,
with the cost of solar also declining far more rapidly than the cost of wind.
In the Low Renewables Cost Case, however, the cost of wind and solar are very
similar initially, with the overnight capital cost of solar eventually falling
below the cost of wind. In the High Renewables Cost case, the overnight capital
costs of solar and wind are frozen at their 2019 levels. This means even though
solar is forecast to drop below wind very quickly in the Reference case, this
does not occur in the High Renewables Cost case, and solar remains more
expensive than wind throughout the forecast window.
Next, consider the High Oil and Gas
Supply and Low Oil and Gas Supply scenarios. The High Oil and Gas Supply
scenario assumes 50 percent higher well output and 50 percent higher
technological improvements than the Reference case.[27] The
Low Oil and Gas Supply case assumes 50 percent lower well output and 50 percent
lower technological improvement than the Reference case.[28] The
resulting forecasts for natural gas production are given in figure E.3.
Figure
E.3 U.S. electricity generation from
selected fuels, Reference, and alternative Oil and Gas Supply scenarios (in
terawatt-hours)
Source: EIA, AEO2020 Full Report, January 29, 2020, 58.
Note: Underlying data for this figure can be found in appendix
tables G.45, G.46, and G.47.
The AEO’s graphs of electricity
generation in the Reference case show that generation from renewables is
projected to pass generation from natural gas by around 2045. In the High Oil
and Gas Supply case, however, natural gas is projected to remain the primary
source of electricity generation throughout the forecast window, and the
projected output of electricity from renewables is projected to be below the
Reference case projections. In the Low Oil and Gas Supply case, electricity
generation from renewables is projected to be much greater than in the
Reference case by the end of the forecast window, with generation from natural
gas dropping by about a third compared to its 2019 level before leveling off
around 2030.
Model Outputs
Effects on the Price of Wholesale Generation
Massachusetts’s new commitments lead to
additional generation when they are incentivizing. As a result, the commitments
increase electricity supply in New England, lowering the price of generation
available to Massachusetts utilities. The model estimates future reductions in
the price of generation in New England using projections of future prices of
electricity in New England for a case with the updated RPS in place and another
case, the RPS Sunset case, with no RPS or CES.[29] The
difference between these two price projections, prorated by the difference
between Massachusetts’s initial and updated RPS plus the part of
Massachusetts’s CES share above the updated RPS that is not met by
hydroelectric resources in the baseline, is the estimated negative price effect
of the updated RPS.
The estimated policy-induced reductions
in the price of generation are small, and the effects of the additional CES are
zero in most years or very small in 2050. The model applies the ratio of the
changes in commitment shares to adjust the estimated reduction in the price of
generation in New England observed going from the RPS Sunset case to the
Reference case. Equation (E6) defines the wholesale price effect (WPE):
(E6)
where Ih
is one if Sh < Sc – Su and is zero otherwise; where the prices PRef and PSunset
are the AEO’s projected prices for New England in the Reference case and RPS
Sunset case, respectively; and where SNE is equal to Massachusetts’s
share of total New England load (45.6 percent). The first term of equation (E6)
is the estimated price effect of the RPS commitments of all 30 policies
nationwide as compared to the situation if there were no state-level RPS commitments.
The second term of the equation is the prorating factor, which prorates the
total effect by the amount of renewables required to meet Massachusetts’s RPS
and CES commitments, (Sc – Su)
+ Ih ((Sc – Su)
– Sh), divided by the increase in
Massachusetts’s commitment going from the Reference case to the RPS Sunset case
(equal to zero), Su – 0. The final term
further prorates the New England price effect by multiplying it by
Massachusetts’s share of New England’s total load.
Effects on the Costs to Massachusetts Consumers
The effects of the standards on costs to
residential and commercial electricity customers in Massachusetts will be
determined mostly by the increased cost of compliance credits. Equation (E7)
estimates the change in the costs of the credits, ΔCredit,
to Massachusetts consumers, in 2019 constant dollars per MWh:
(E7)
where Ih
is one if Sh < Sc – Su and is zero otherwise. The effects of the
standards on the total costs to consumers also include the small estimated
policy-induced reduction in the price of generation discussed above. Equation
(E8) defines the total cost to consumers inclusive of the credit and the price
reduction in 2019 constant dollars per MWh:
(E8)
where ΔCredit
is defined in equation (E7); Iv is one if VOC1 > 0
(i.e., the policy is incentivizing) and is zero otherwise; and WPE is defined in
equation (E6). For the share of load covered by the standard, any reduction in
the price of generation will require an increase in the value of the compliance
credits in order to maintain the profitability of the new generation, so this
price reduction has no net effect on Massachusetts consumers. The reduction in
the price of generation will likely mitigate some of the increased costs from
compliance credits, but this effect will likely be relatively minor. From
equation (E8), WPE is applied to the share of generation that is not satisfied
by renewable generation. Simplifying the second term of the equation, if the
share of hydro is large enough that no clean energy needs to be incentivized,
then the wholesale price effect equals (1 – Su)
WPE. If the share of hydro is not large enough to satisfy Massachusetts’s CES,
then all of the new renewables built to satisfy Massachusetts’s RPS also
receive credits, so the price effect is applied to the share of generation not
satisfied by renewables, now equal to (1 – (Sc – Sh))
WPE.
The model then calculates the total
dollar value of the change in costs to consumers for each of the future years
by multiplying the estimated change per MWh by the estimated Massachusetts
non-municipal load in the year.
Effects on the Costs to New England Consumers
As discussed in chapter 3 of this report,
the costs for the Massachusetts RPS and CES commitments from the compliance
credits would be paid only by Massachusetts consumers; the economic effects of
the commitments for the rest of New England would be limited to impacts on the
price of generation in the region.
The model calculates the total dollar
value of the change in costs to New England consumers for each of the future
years by multiplying the estimated effect on the price of generation per MWh,
as defined in the equation (E6), by the estimated New England load net of
Massachusetts in the year.
Effects on Massachusetts Emissions
To the extent that the standards lead to
more renewable or clean generation, they will reduce the greenhouse gas
emissions associated with Massachusetts electricity loads. The model
approximates the reduction in carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions based
on the estimated increase in renewable and clean sourcing by assuming that the
renewable and clean sources replace natural gas generation, since natural gas
generation is the next-lowest-cost resource.[30]
Table E.7 lists these CO2 emissions rates.
Table
E.7
Carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions rate of natural gas generation in New
England, Reference case (in million metric tons per megawatt-hour)
Measure |
2030 |
2035 |
2040 |
2045 |
2050 |
CO2 emissions
rate |
0.411 |
0.392 |
0.429 |
0.437 |
0.447 |
Source: USITC
calculations.
If clean generation is profitable absent
incentives from Massachusetts’s CES or RPS, then although new production from
clean resources will reduce emissions, those reductions will not count toward
the estimated policy-induced reductions in emissions. This is
why in some years the model does not project any policy-induced
reductions in emissions.
Equation (E9) estimates the
policy-induced change in emissions associated with Massachusetts’s load, in
millions of metric tons per MWh:
(E9)
Iv is equal to one if VOC1
> 0 and zero otherwise. erng is the CO2
emissions rate for displaced natural gas generation in New England (table E.7).
The model calculates the total policy-induced change in CO2 emissions
in each of the future years by multiplying the estimated change per MWh by the
estimated non-municipal load in Massachusetts in a given year.
Data Sources
The model includes data
from many different sources.
·
The data on the renewable and clean
energy commitment shares in table E.1 are from the Massachusetts state
implementing legislation.
·
The model takes into
account the fact that the aspects of Massachusetts’s RPS and CES modeled
in this report generally apply only to investor-owned utilities and not to
municipal providers by netting out the share of electricity sales coming from
municipal providers. Data on the share of electricity from municipal providers
are pulled from the EIA’s state electricity profile for Massachusetts table on
Retail Electricity Sales Statistics for 2018 (the most recent available data).[31]
The model assumes this rate remains stable over the span of the model at its
2018 level of approximately 14.1 percent.
·
The data on future loads in Massachusetts
are calculated using EIA’s AEO projections on net energy for New England load
in the future years, adjusted for the share of Massachusetts load in total New
England load reported by ISO New England and also for the share of
Massachusetts load served by municipal utilities.
·
The share of Massachusetts in New
England’s total load is assumed to remain constant at the levels in the most
recent data available (2018), equal to 45.6 percent. Massachusetts’s share is
found by dividing the Massachusetts load estimates from EIA by ISO New England’s
estimates of total load.[32]
·
The data on the share of Massachusetts
non-municipal load served by imported hydroelectric resources in table E.2 are
calculated from the EIA’s AEO projections for New England’s international and
interregional imports (prorated for the share of these international and
interregional imports that are hydroelectric generation), assuming that the
shares serving Massachusetts are the same as the shares in total New England
load. The share of New England’s imports coming from hydroelectric generation
is extrapolated from the most recent available NEPOOL estimates. In September
2018, 24.8 percent of imports from New York State were from hydroelectric
generation. In October 2018, 96.0 percent of imports from Quebec were from
hydroelectric generation.[33]
·
The average revenue estimates for the
marginal new renewable generation in New England are based on EIA’s levelized avoided cost of electricity (LACE) for the
five AEO 2020 cases. The model uses EIA projections at the regional level,
defined by ISO New England. Detailed data for each year, plant type, and case
for the New England region were provided by EIA. LACE measures the revenue
available to a new generator over a 30-year cost recovery period. EIA estimates
revenue opportunities for the additional generation on an hour-by-hour basis
over the full life cycle of the generation plant. LACE accounts for variation
in daily and seasonal electricity demand and for the characteristics of the
existing generation fleet to which new capacity will be added.
·
The average cost estimates for the
marginal new renewable generation in New England are based on EIA’s levelized
cost of electricity (LCOE) estimates for the five AEO 2020 cases. Additional
underlying data for each year, plant type, and case for the New England region
are provided by EIA. LCOE measures the revenue required to build and operate a
new generator over a 30-year cost recovery period. It is calculated by EIA
based on engineering estimates of building, operating, and maintenance costs over
the full life cycle of the generation plant. It incorporates projections of
future technology, fuel costs, and many other factors.[34]
·
The model estimates future reductions in
the price of generation in New England using simulation results reported in the
2020 AEO. EIA projects future prices of electricity in the New England region
for its Reference case (which includes Massachusetts’s pre-2016 RPS but not its
CES or the 2018 update of its RPS) and the RPS Sunset case (with no RPS).
·
Estimates of the cost to residential
consumers per household per month are calculated by first finding the average
consumption per household per month in Massachusetts. This is calculated using
AEO’s forecasts for residential electrical energy use for New England,
adjusting by the share of electricity load in New England going to
Massachusetts (about 45.6 percent), and then dividing by the number of
residential customers in Massachusetts according to the AEO’s state electricity
profile. This makes the estimate potentially on the higher end, as it does not
allow an increase in the number of residential consumers over the time period but instead assumes the number of retail
customers remains constant from the 2018 levels. An alternative cost estimate
in which the number of residential consumers grows according to a linear trend
is included later in this appendix.[35]
·
Emissions rates are calculated using AEO
forecasts. Specifically, for each of the five cases considered in the
Commission model, AEO forecasts the level of generation and carbon emissions by
resource type over the span of the model. Taking the projected emissions from
natural gas generation in a given year (the lowest-cost displaced resource) and
dividing by the projected generation from natural gas in that same year yields
the projected emissions per megawatt-hour of electricity coming from non-clean
resources.
Additional Results
Alternative Scenarios: Cost to New England Consumers and
Greenhouse Gas Estimates
In chapter 3, table 3.9 reports the
estimated cost saving for the rest of New England (excluding Massachusetts)
resulting from Massachusetts’s recent commitments. The corresponding estimates
for the High and Low Renewables Cost cases and the High and Low Oil and Gas
Supply cases are presented in table E.8.
Table E.8 Estimated savings for New England,
excluding Massachusetts, due to Massachusetts’s commitments (in 2019 dollars)
Year |
Price effect
if incentivizing (cents per kWh) |
Total annual
savings, High Renewables Cost case (million $) |
Total annual
savings, Low
Renewables Cost case (million $) |
Total annual
savings, High Oil and
Gas Supply case (million $) |
Total annual
savings, Low Oil and
Gas Supply case (million $) |
2030 |
-0.0013 |
0.87 |
0.87 |
0.87 |
0 |
2035 |
-0.0044 |
3.00 |
0 |
3.00 |
0 |
2040 |
-0.0021 |
1.50 |
0 |
1.49 |
0 |
2045 |
-0.0044 |
3.22 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2050 |
-0.0031 |
2.44 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source:
USITC calculations.
Note:
The price effect is calculated using the comparison of AEO estimated prices in
the Reference case and the RPS Sunset case. The model assumes the same cent per
kWh price effect in the other cases but zeroes out the total price effect when
the policy is not incentivizing the addition of renewables. The calculation of
the price effect is discussed further with equation (E6).
The total annual savings are calculated
using the AEO projections for net energy for load for each scenario multiplied
by the price effect per kWh. Because the price effect does not change between
cases, the total annual savings are relatively constant across all five
scenarios (including the Reference case).
In chapter 3, table 3.10 reports the
estimated reduction in carbon dioxide emissions rates associated with the shift
in electricity consumed within Massachusetts due to the new RPS and CES
commitments, in million metric tons per MWh, and total carbon dioxide emissions
reductions for each of the model years using data from the AEO 2020 Reference
case. The corresponding estimates for the High and Low Renewables Cost cases
and the High and Low Oil and Gas Supply cases are presented here in both
millions of metric tons (Mmt), table E.9, and
millions of metric tons per MWh (Mmt per MWh), table
E.10.
Table
E.9
Estimated effect of commitments on carbon dioxide emissions per MWh in
Massachusetts, alternative scenarios (in million metric tons, Mmt, per MWh)
Year |
Reference case |
High
Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables
Cost case |
High Oil and
Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and
Gas Supply case |
2030 |
-0.041 |
-0.041 |
-0.041 |
-0.042 |
0 |
2035 |
-0.039 |
-0.042 |
0 |
-0.043 |
0 |
2040 |
0 |
-0.044 |
0 |
-0.043 |
0 |
2045 |
0 |
-0.065 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2050 |
0 |
-0.089 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source: USITC calculations.
Table
E.10
Estimated effect of commitments on total carbon dioxide emissions in
Massachusetts, alternative scenarios (in million metric tons, Mmt)
Year |
Reference case |
High
Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables
Cost case |
High Oil and
Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and
Gas Supply case |
2030 |
-1.94 |
-1.95 |
-1.94 |
-1.99 |
0 |
2035 |
-1.91 |
-2.06 |
0 |
-2.10 |
0 |
2040 |
0 |
-2.23 |
0 |
-2.19 |
0 |
2045 |
0 |
-3.42 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2050 |
0 |
-4.93 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source: USITC calculations.
Because the alternative
cases are only adjusting underlying costs and supplies of resources, the
reductions in emissions do not vary significantly from scenario to scenario for
the years in which the policies are incentivizing. This is evident across the estimates
in tables E.9 and E.10, with the Reference case estimates in 2030 and 2035
being very similar to those estimates in the alternative cases.
For the High Renewables
Cost case, the reduction in emissions is forecast to increase over the
timeframe of the commitments, both on a per-MWh basis and in total emissions
reductions. The reduction in carbon dioxide emissions increases over time as
the commitments become more ambitious through 2050. For the Low Renewables Cost
case, on the other hand, the commitments are only incentivizing in the earliest
projection year. For the High Oil and Gas Supply case, reductions in carbon
emissions are very similar to the estimates for the High Renewables Cost case
in the years in which the commitments are incentivizing (through 2040).
Sensitivity Analysis of Assumptions
In this section, the
some of the model’s underlying assumptions are modified to provide sensitivity
analysis for the results. Table 3.2 outlines the key assumptions used in the
modeling that are relaxed in the following section. First, the chapter 3
estimates assume that marginal new renewable generation is from solar PV
facilities; in the first subsection below, the cost to consumers is calculated
for when wind is the marginal resource. Second, chapter 3 estimates assume that
Massachusetts’s access to imports is proportional to its load as a share of
total New England load; the second subsection below calculates the cost to
consumers in the Reference case when Massachusetts has moderate, low, and no
access to these imports. Finally, chapter 3 calculations of the monthly cost to
consumers assume there is no growth in the number of residential and commercial
customers in Massachusetts; the final subsection below presents the monthly
cost to consumers when the number of customers is allowed to grow following a
linear trend.
Wind as the Marginal Resource
The following set of estimates present an
alternative scenario in which, instead of solar PV resources being the marginal
resource filling Massachusetts’s RPS and CES commitments, onshore wind
generation is the marginal resource. Tables E.11 and E.12 show the cost to
consumers of the commitments, assuming the marginal commitments are filled by
new onshore wind construction.
Table
E.11
Estimated increase in per-unit cost to Massachusetts consumers with onshore
wind as the marginal resource (in 2019 cents per kWh)
Year |
Reference case |
High Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables Cost case |
High Oil and Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and Gas Supply case |
2030 |
0.072 |
0.089 |
0.012 |
0.082 |
0.009 |
2035 |
0.050 |
0.082 |
0 |
0.061 |
0 |
2040 |
0.020 |
0.192 |
0 |
0.047 |
0 |
2045 |
0 |
0.235 |
0 |
0.070 |
0 |
2050 |
0 |
0.184 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source: USITC calculations.
Table
E.12
Estimated increase in total cost to Massachusetts consumers with onshore wind
as the marginal resource (in millions of 2019 dollars)
Year |
Reference case |
High Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables Cost case |
High Oil and Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and Gas Supply case |
2030 |
34.2 |
42.4 |
5.8 |
39.0 |
4.3 |
2035 |
24.5 |
40.5 |
0 |
30.1 |
0 |
2040 |
10.0 |
97.9 |
0 |
24.0 |
0 |
2045 |
0 |
124.4 |
0 |
36.9 |
0 |
2050 |
0 |
102.0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source: USITC calculations.
Comparing tables E.11
and E.12 to tables 3.5 and 3.6, the results for wind show a significant
departure from the predicted costs to consumers if solar is the marginal
resource. Compared to the Reference case, wind being the marginal resource
results in a cost to consumers about 75 percent higher than if solar is the
marginal resource in 2030, and about 110 percent greater in 2035. Additionally,
Massachusetts’s increased commitments continue to be costly to consumers in
2040, while if solar is the marginal resource they are not. These increasing
differences between the cost to consumers when the marginal demand is satisfied
by wind reflect the fact that the rate of overnight capital cost reductions
from wind is slower than the rate of cost reductions for solar PV energy
generation.[36]
For the alternative
cases, however, the cost to consumers is lower when wind is the marginal
resource both for the High Renewables Cost case and the Low Renewables Cost
case. For the High Renewables Cost case, this is a result of the way that the
AEO constructs the overnight cost of capital, as was discussed in the
“Background on AEO Scenarios” section of this appendix (the High Renewables
Cost case freezes the capital costs for solar and wind, leading to the price of
solar never falling below the price of wind). For the Low Renewables Cost case,
solar is less expensive to build than wind by around 2022 (see figure E.2), but
the profitability of wind is still forecast to be greater through 2040 (see
tables E.13 and E.14). As a result, the cost of the commitments is about 50
percent lower in 2030 with wind as the marginal resource. For the High
Renewables Cost scenario, the commitments cost between 20 and 40 percent less
over the projected time frame if wind is the marginal resource rather than
solar.
Similar
to the Reference case, commitments in the
High Oil and Gas Supply and Low Oil and Gas Supply cases are higher across the
board when wind is the marginal resource. The underlying structures of the Oil
and Gas Supply scenarios do not make changes to the profitability of
renewables, so it is unsurprising that the ranking of the resources does not
change. The Oil and Gas Supply scenarios affect only the next-best resource.
Table E.13 and E.14
include the AEO’s projected profitability for the wind and solar as reference
for the discussion in this section.
Table
E.13
Profitability (average revenue minus average cost) of solar (photovoltaic) in
New England for all scenarios (in 2019 dollars per megawatt-hour)
Scenario |
2030 |
2035 |
2040 |
2045 |
2050 |
Reference |
-3.87 |
-2.23 |
1.94 |
3.03 |
3.21 |
High Renewables Cost |
-11.62 |
-11.04 |
-9.76 |
-9.51 |
-7.63 |
Low Renewables
Cost |
-2.43 |
1.09 |
4.32 |
5.94 |
6.95 |
High Oil and Gas Supply |
-4.15 |
-1.73 |
-0.06 |
0.61 |
3.19 |
Low Oil and Gas
Supply |
0.30 |
4.59 |
7.80 |
8.71 |
9.01 |
Source: EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020: LACE (available from
EIA on request; accessed October 2, 2020); EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020:
LCOE (available from EIA on request; accessed October 2, 2020).
Table
E.14
Profitability (average revenue minus average cost) of onshore wind in New
England for all scenarios (in 2019 dollars per megawatt-hour)
Scenario |
2030 |
2035 |
2040 |
2045 |
2050 |
Reference |
-6.97 |
-4.87 |
-0.60 |
0.53 |
1.55 |
High Renewables Cost |
-8.65 |
-8.08 |
-7.51 |
-7.41 |
-4.33 |
Low Renewables
Cost |
-0.98 |
2.52 |
4.94 |
5.73 |
6.08 |
High Oil and Gas Supply |
-7.91 |
-5.96 |
-4.31 |
-2.03 |
0.53 |
Low Oil and Gas
Supply |
-0.68 |
1.37 |
4.86 |
6.06 |
6.09 |
Source: EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020: LACE (available from
EIA on request; accessed October 2, 2020); EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020:
LCOE (available from EIA on request; accessed October 2, 2020).
Varying Access to Imports
As discussed previously, the modeling
elsewhere in the report assumes that Massachusetts receives 45.6 percent of New
England’s total imports, since Massachusetts accounts for 45.6 percent of New
England’s load. For this section, that assumption is relaxed, and the model
examines how the results change if Massachusetts’s access to imports is
lowered. This case reflects the fact that Massachusetts is geographically
farther from Canada and New York State than the majority of
other New England states.[37]
Lowering Massachusetts’s access to
imports impacts the model through the CES commitments: when access to imports
is low, Massachusetts will be filling a larger share of its CES commitments
with the lowest-cost resource that fits into the clean or renewable category.
As discussed earlier, the model uses solar PV generation as this resource.
For the Reference case, recall that the
commitments are costly only to consumers for 2030 and 2035. In these periods,
the difference between Massachusetts’s RPS and CES is small—5 percent in 2030
and 10 percent in 2035. Therefore, in those years, access to imports does
not need to be large for hydroelectricity to be able to satisfy the entirety of
the clean energy commitment.
The effect of varying access to imports
for the High Renewables Cost case is provided as an illustration of the effect
that imports have on the costs to consumers (tables E.15 and E.16). For the
High Renewables cost case, reducing access to imports does not affect costs in
the early years, as was also true for the Reference case. For the High
Renewables Cost case with the baseline level of imports, recall that a small
share of Massachusetts’s CES was met by renewables (reflected by the jump in
the cost to consumers in 2040). If Massachusetts has moderate or low access to
imports, then renewables are needed to meet CES commitments as early as 2040.
Table
E.15
Estimated increase in per-unit cost to consumers of Massachusetts’s increased
commitments, varying levels of access to imports, High Renewables Cost Case (in
2019 cents per kWh)
Year |
Baseline
imports (45.6 percent) |
Moderate
access (30 percent) |
Low access (20
percent) |
2030 |
0.119 |
0.119 |
0.119 |
2035 |
0.112 |
0.222a |
0.225a |
2040 |
0.249a |
0.254a |
0.259a |
2045 |
0.298a |
0.308a |
0.315a |
2050 |
0.299a |
0.317a |
0.331a |
a A
share of the Clean Energy Standard commitment above the Renewable Portfolio
Standard is being met by renewable generation.
Source: USITC calculations.
Table
E.16
Estimated increase in total cost to consumers of Massachusetts’s increased
commitments, varying levels of access to imports, High Renewables Cost Case (in
millions of 2019 dollars)
Year |
Baseline
imports (45.6 percent) |
Moderate
access (30 percent) |
Low access (20
percent) |
2030 |
56.5 |
56.5 |
56.5 |
2035 |
55.0 |
109.2a |
110.3a |
2040 |
126.6a |
129.5a |
131.7a |
2045 |
157.7a |
162.8a |
166.9a |
2050 |
165.9a |
175.5a |
183.5a |
a A share of the Clean Energy Standard
commitment above the Renewable Portfolio Standard is being met by renewable
generation.
Source: USITC calculations.
As discussed in chapter
3 of this report, assuming Massachusetts has no access to imports results in a
significant increase in the cost to consumers of Massachusetts’s increased
commitments in many of the years of the model projections. The complete results
of this estimation of cost to consumers are in tables E.17 and E.18.
Table
E.17
Estimated increase in per-unit cost to consumers of Massachusetts’s increased
commitments if Massachusetts has no access to imported hydroelectricity (in
2019 cents per kWh)
Year |
Reference case |
High
Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables
Cost case |
High Oil and
Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and
Gas Supply case |
2030 |
0.064 |
0.180 |
0.042 |
0.068 |
0 |
2035 |
0.057 |
0.231 |
0 |
0.045 |
0 |
2040 |
0 |
0.270 |
0 |
0.024 |
0 |
2045 |
0 |
0.336 |
0 |
0.001 |
0 |
2050 |
0 |
0.374 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source: USITC
calculations.
Table
E.18
Estimated increase in total cost to consumers of Massachusetts’s increased
commitments if Massachusetts has no access to imported hydroelectricity (in
millions of 2019 dollars)
Year |
Reference case |
High
Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables
Cost case |
High Oil and
Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and
Gas Supply case |
2030 |
30.2 |
85.6 |
19.9 |
32.4 |
0 |
2035 |
27.6 |
113.3 |
0 |
21.9 |
0 |
2040 |
0 |
137.4 |
0 |
12.1 |
0 |
2045 |
0 |
177.9 |
0 |
0.7 |
0 |
2050 |
0 |
207.2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source: USITC
calculations.
A discussion of the changes
in costs as compared to the model estimates with access to imports (detailed in
table 3.11) is in chapter 3.
Residential and Commercial Customer Growth
The following table reports the cost to
consumers if instead of holding constant the number of retail and commercial
customers at the 2018 levels, these numbers are allowed to increase following a
linear trend based on Massachusetts retail and commercial customer growth
observed between 1990 and 2018. This set of estimates would present a likely lower
bound for the cost to consumers, whereas the estimates in tables 3.7 and 3.8
are an upper bound, as they assume a lower number of customers in each
category. Tables E.19 and E.20 depict the results when residential customers
and commercial customers grow according to the linear trend for completeness.
Table
E.19
Estimated increase in the cost to residential consumers for high population
growth, monthly cost per customer (in 2019 dollars)
Year |
Reference case |
High
Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables
Cost case |
High Oil and
Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and
Gas Supply case |
2030 |
0.24 |
0.70 |
0.16 |
0.26 |
0 |
2035 |
0.14 |
0.67 |
0 |
0.11 |
0 |
2040 |
0 |
1.50 |
0 |
0.01 |
0 |
2045 |
0 |
1.82 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2050 |
0 |
1.85 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source: USITC
calculations.
Table
E.20
Estimated increase in the cost to commercial consumers for high population
growth, monthly cost per customer (in 2019 dollars)
Year |
Reference case |
High
Renewables Cost case |
Low Renewables
Cost case |
High Oil and
Gas Supply case |
Low Oil and
Gas Supply case |
2030 |
1.60 |
4.71 |
1.04 |
1.73 |
0 |
2035 |
0.90 |
4.29 |
0 |
0.72 |
0 |
2040 |
0 |
9.34 |
0 |
0.05 |
0 |
2045 |
0 |
11.12 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2050 |
0 |
11.25 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Source: USITC
calculations.
Bibliography
Barbose, Galen. U.S. Renewables Portfolio Standards: 2019 Annual Status Update.
Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, July 2019. https://eta-publications.lbl.gov/sites/default/files/rps_annual_status_update-2019_edition.pdf.
Biello, David. “Nuclear Reactor Approved in
U.S. for First Time since 1978.” Scientific
American, February 9, 2012. https://www.scientificamerican.com/article/first-new-nuclear-reactor-in-us-since-1978-approved/.
EIA.
See U.S. Energy Information
Administration (EIA).
Heeter, J., G. Barbose,
L. Bird, S. Weaver, and R. Wiser. A
Survey of State-Level Cost and Benefit Estimates of Renewable Portfolio
Standards. National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL), May 2014. https://www.nrel.gov/docs/fy14osti/61042.pdf.
Hydro-Québec.
Written submission to the U.S. International Trade Commission in connection
with Inv. No. 332-574, Renewable
Electricity: Potential Economic Effects of Increased Commitments in
Massachusetts, August 7, 2020.
ISO
New England. “Net Energy and Peak Load by Source,” n.d. https://www.iso-ne.com/isoexpress/web/reports/load-and-demand/-/tree/net-ener-peak-load (accessed March 24,
2020).
Knight,
Pat, Ariel Horowitz, Patrick Luckow, Tyler Comings,
Jason Gifford, Po-Yu Yuen, Edward Snook, and Jordan Shoesmith.
An Analysis of the Massachusetts
Renewable Portfolio Standard. Prepared by
Synapse Energy Economics
and Sustainable Energy Advantage for NECEC Institute, May
2017. https://www.synapse-energy.com/sites/default/files/Analysis-MA-RPS-17-004.pdf.
New
England Power Pool (NEPOOL). General Information System. System Mix. https://www1.nepoolgis.com/myModule/rpt/ssrs.asp?rn=107&r=%2FPROD%2FNEPOOLGIS%2FPublic%2FNEPOOL_ImportSystemMix&apxReportTitle=Import%20System%20Mix
(accessed November 3, 2020)
Stanton,
Elizabeth A., Tyler Comings, Rachel Wilson, Sagal Alisalad, Emrat Nur Marzan, Nina Schlegel, Bryndis
Woods, Jason Gifford, Edward Snook, and Po-Yu Yuen. An Analysis of the Massachusetts 2018 “Act to Promote a Clean Energy
Future.” Prepared by the Applied Economics Clinic for the Massachusetts
Senate Committee on Global Warming and Climate Change, June 21, 2018. https://aeclinic.org/publicationpages/2018/6/18/an-analysis-of-the-massachusetts-2018-act-to-promote-a-clean-energy-future.
State
of Massachusetts. “Program Summaries: Summaries of all the Renewable and
Alternative Energy Portfolio Standard programs,” n.d. https://www.mass.gov/service-details/program-summaries
(accessed September 16, 2020).
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Annual
Energy Outlook 2020 [AEO 2020]: Full Report, January 29, 2020. https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/pdf/AEO2020%20Full%20Report.pdf.
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Annual Energy Outlook 2020: Levelized
Avoided Cost of Electricity (LACE) for New Generation Resources in Region 7—New
England by Online Year (available from EIA on request; accessed October 2,
2020).
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Annual Energy Outlook 2020: Levelized
Cost of Electricity (LCOE) for New Generation Resources for Region 7—New
England by Online Year (available from EIA on request; accessed October 2,
2020).
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Capital
Cost Estimates for Utility Scale Electricity Generating Plants, November
2016. https://www.eia.gov/analysis/studies/powerplants/capitalcost/pdf/capcost_assumption.pdf.
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Commercial
Demand Module of the National Energy Modeling System: Model Documentation,
October 2018. https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/nems/documentation/commercial/pdf/m066(2018).pdf.
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). “Glossary,” n.d. https://www.eia.gov/tools/glossary/index.php?id=E
(accessed September 21, 2020).
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Levelized
Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources in the Annual
Energy Outlook 2020, February 2020. https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/pdf/electricity_generation.pdf.
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Residential
Demand Module of the National Energy Modeling System: Model Documentation 2020,
June 2020. https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo/nems/documentation/residential/pdf/m067(2020).pdf.
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Table 8: Retail Sales, Revenue, and
Average Retail Price by Sector; State Electricity Profiles. https://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/massachusetts/state_tables.php
(accessed March 24, 2020).
U.S.
Energy Information Administration (EIA). Table 9: Retail Electricity Sales
Statistics; State Electricity Profiles. https://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/massachusetts/state_tables.php
(accessed March 24, 2020).
[1] Summarized in more detail in a footnote at the beginning of chapter 3.
[2] Knight et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts Renewable Portfolio Standard, May 2017, iii, v.
[3] Stanton et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts 2018 ‘Act,’ June 21, 2018, i.
[5] Knight et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts Renewable Portfolio Standard, May 2017, 24. More information on the supply-side commitments of the 2016 Act are available in a footnote at the beginning of this chapter.
[6] Knight et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts Renewable Portfolio Standard, May 2017, 26.
[7] Knight et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts Renewable Portfolio Standard, May 2017, 30.
[8] Knight et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts Renewable Portfolio Standard, May 2017, 30.
[9] Stanton et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts 2018 ‘Act,’ June 21, 2018, 6.
[10] Stanton et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts 2018 ‘Act,’ June 21, 2018, i.
[11] Stanton et al., An Analysis of the Massachusetts 2018 ‘Act,’ June 21, 2018, 9.
[12] The Class II RPS did not change after 2016, so Class II commitments are not part of the estimated effects of the policy changes in 2017–19. For more information about Massachusetts’s Class II commitments, see chapter 2 of this report.
[13] References to “renewable” and “clean” in this appendix refer to resources eligible for the Massachusetts commitments specifically. This means, for example, that large-scale hydroelectricity is considered clean but not renewable. See chapter 2 of this report for more details on qualifying sources of electricity under Massachusetts’s commitments.
[14] Again, note that the old RPS commitments, So, and the updated RPS commitments, Su, represent the Class I commitments by Massachusetts, which also qualify for the CES commitments. Massachusetts’s Class II commitments, which account for approximately 6 percent of total sales, do not qualify to fill the clean energy commitments in the CES, which is why the modeling examines the resources that will potentially fill the share Sc – Su . For further discussion of the classes of resources in Massachusetts’s commitments, see chapter 2 of this report.
[15] “Act to Advance Clean Energy (H4857)” (2018); “Clean Energy Standard,” 310 CMR 7.75 (2017), 509, 513–14; EIA, Table 9: Retail Electricity Sales Statistics, (accessed September 16, 2020).
[16] NEPOOL General Information System, System Mix (accessed November 3, 2020).
[17] International transmissions connections have
historically been very stable. For example, the last transmission line between
New York or New England and Quebec was constructed 30 years ago (though it is
worth noting there are plans underway to expand transmission between the
regions). Hydro-Québec, written submission to USITC, August 7, 2020, 39. Again,
our model is not considering the effects of any existing or potential contracts
to expand transmission. However, such contracts could increase Massachusetts’s
access to imports.
[18] EIA projects that the LCOE will be far greater for hydroelectricity and nuclear than for wind and solar in 2025 in the United States. EIA, “Levelized Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources in the Annual Energy Outlook 2020,” February 2020, 7.
[19] EIA, Commercial Demand Module, October 2018, 200; EIA, Residential Demand Module, June 2020, 120.
[20] EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020: LACE (available from EIA on request; accessed October 2, 2020); EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020: LCOE (available from EIA on request; accessed October 2, 2020). As discussed in chapter 3, and in box 3.2 specifically, the RPS Sunset case provides an additional rationale to assume that solar will grow to meet Massachusetts’s commitments.
[21] Barbose, U.S. Renewables Portfolio Standards, 2019, 33.
[22] Barbose, U.S. Renewables Portfolio Standards, 2019, 33.
[22] Barbose, U.S. Renewables Portfolio Standards, 2019, 33.
[23] Biello, “Nuclear Reactor Approved,” February 9, 2012.
[24] U.S. Energy Information Administration, “Annual Energy Outlook 2020, Full Report,” January 29, 2020, 5.
[25] EIA, “Annual Energy Outlook 2020: Case Descriptions,” January 2020, 6; EIA “Capital Cost Estimates for Utility Scale Electricity Generating Plants,” 1.
[26] EIA, “Annual Energy Outlook 2020: Case Descriptions,” January 2020, 6.
[27] EIA, “Annual Energy Outlook 2020: Case Descriptions,” January 2020, 5–6. EIA defines technological improvements here as improvements that may lead to the development of crude oil and natural gas resources that have not yet been identified.
[28] EIA, “Annual Energy Outlook 2020: Case Descriptions,” January 2020, 5.
[29] Box 3.2 provides additional discussion of the RPS Sunset case, including how its projections compare to the Reference case results.
[30] Note that this is reflected in table 2.5 in chapter 2, which shows that natural gas supplies the largest share of generation in Massachusetts.
[31] EIA, Table 9: Retail Electricity Sales Statistics (accessed Sept 16, 2020).
[32] ISO New England, “Net Energy and Peak Load by Source” (accessed March 24, 2020); EIA, “State Electricity Profiles” (accessed March 24, 2020).
[33] NEPOOL General Information System, System Mix (accessed November 3, 2020).
[34] Calculations for LCOE (and LACE) include state and federal tax incentives, state-level renewable energy targets. EIA, “Levelized Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost,” February 2020, 4–5.
[35] EIA, Table 8: Retail Sales (accessed September 15, 2020).
[36] See discussion of figure E.2 or table 3.2.
[37] Massachusetts does not share a border with Canada and borders the downstate portion of New York’s electricity grid (which has significantly less hydropower than the upstate portion; see chapter 4 for more discussion of New York’s electricity market).