A COMPARISON OF PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM
MODELS
OF TARIFF RATE QUOTAS
Ross Hallren
David Riker
ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES
Working Paper 2017-09-B
U.S. INTERNATIONAL TRADE COMMISSION
500 E Street SW
Washington, DC 20436
September 2017
Office of Economics
working papers are the result of ongoing professional research of USITC Staff
and are solely meant to represent the opinions and professional research of
individual authors. These papers are not meant to represent in any way the
views of the U.S. International Trade Commission or any of its individual
Commissioners. Working papers are circulated to promote the active exchange of
ideas between USITC Staff and recognized experts outside the USITC and to
promote professional development of Office Staff by encouraging outside
professional critique of staff research.
A Comparison of
Partial Equilibrium Models of Tariff Rate Quotas
Ross Hallren and David Riker
Office of Economics Working Paper 2017-09-B
September 2017
ABSTRACT
In
this short paper we consider the impact of a TRQ on industry-specific imports
and domestic production using two different types of partial equilibrium
models, an Armington CES model and a Krugman CES model of trade. In the
Armington model with only adjustment on the intensive margin of trade, a TRQ
that fills has the same effect on trade as a flat tariff at the out-of-quota
rate. On the other hand, when there is also adjustment on the extensive margin
of trade, as in a Krugman or Melitz model of trade, the two policies are not
equivalent and the in-quota rate has an effect on trade and domestic production
even when the TRQ fills.
Ross
Hallren
Office
of Economics, Research Division
Ross.Hallren@usitc.gov
David
Riker
Office
of Economics, Research Division
David.Riker@usitc.gov
1.
Introduction
A
tariff rate quota (TRQ) is a tariff schedule with a step: there is an in-quota
tariff rate on import volumes below the quota volume and a higher out-of-quota
tariff rate on imports above the quota volume. In this paper we model the
impact of a TRQ on the volumes of subject imports and domestic production using
two alternative partial equilibrium (PE) models of international trade. Our
first PE model is an Armington (1969) CES model with perfect competition and infinitely
elastic supply. Our second PE model is a Krugman (1980) CES model with product
differentiation, fixed costs of trade and production, and monopolistic
competition.
We
describe the two models and then we run several simulations of changes in trade
policy, using illustrative data inputs, and compare the estimates from the
alternative models. We focus on a scenario in which the TRQ fills, which means
that the volume of subject imports is greater than or equal to the quota volume. In the
Armington CES model, whenever the TRQ fills, the out-of-quota tariff
rate affects the volumes of trade and domestic production, but the in-quota
rate and the TRQ quota amount do not affect trade or domestic production. In
this model, a TRQ with a specific ad valorem out-of-quota rate has the same effect
on trade and domestic production as a flat tariff at the same ad valorem rate.
In
contrast, in a Krugman CES model with fixed costs of trade and production, all
of the parameters of the TRQ (the in-quota rate and quota volume, as well as the
out-of-quota rate) affect the volumes of trade and domestic production, even if
the TRQ fills and the out-of-quota rate applies. In this case, the in-quota
rate affects the incentives for foreign producers to enter the market by
transferring infra-marginal tariff revenues.
2.
Armington
CES Model with Infinite Elasticities of Supply and Perfect Competition
In
the first model, we assume that there is perfect competition and the elasticity
of supply for each producer is infinitely elastic. There are constant returns
to scale and factor prices are set in the broader economy and are not
significantly affected by the policy changes (a partial equilibrium
assumption). Although this is a restrictive assumption about the elasticity of supply,
it makes the Armington model more comparable to the Krugman model discussed
below.
The
prices of producers in source country are
equal to their exogenous marginal costs .
(1)
Equation
(2) is the industry price index for the market.
(2)
The
parameters represent potential asymmetries in
preferences for the domestic and foreign varieties indexed by . The variable is
the applicable tariff rate in the home country on varieties from source country
.
Equation
(3) is the demand function corresponding to the CES preferences.
(3)
The
variable is
total expenditures on all varieties of the product. We assume that is
a constant share of aggregate expenditures (an assumption that there are
Cobb-Douglas preferences between the different industries) and that aggregate expenditures
are exogenous (another partial equilibrium assumption). The tariff rate on
subject imports is equal to the in-quota rate if
is
less than the quota volume and is equal to the out-of-quota rate if
is
greater than the quota volume. (The subscript indicates
imports subject to the TRQ.) We focus
on the second scenario, where the TRQ fills and marginal tariff rate is .
Equation
(4) calibrates the preference parameters if initial prices are set equal to
one.
(4)
The
variable is
the initial market share for the varieties from source country .
We
solve for the change in the volume of subject imports and domestic production due
to the TRQ, holding and fixed, by substituting equations (1) and (4)
into equations (2) and (3). We consider three alternative trade policy scenarios.
In all of the scenarios, the baseline tariff rate is 0 percent. In the first
alternative, the out-of-quota tariff rate is 20 percent and the in-quota rate
is 0 percent. In the second alternative, the out-of-quota rate is higher (30
percent, rather than 20 percent) but the in-quota rate is still 0 percent. In
the third alternative, both the in-quota rate and the out-of-quota rate are 20
percent. This third alternative is equivalent to a flat 20 percent tariff rate on
all import volumes. The model includes three source countries (or groups of
countries) for the products of the industry: domestic production ( ),
subject imports ( )
and imports from the rest of the world ( ).
We
simulate the effects of the policies on the volumes of subject imports and
domestic production using the specific model inputs listed in Table 1. To
illustrate the differences among the policy alternatives, we make several
assumptions about market shares and elasticities. We assume that domestic
producers have a 60 percent market share, while subject imports have a 30
percent share. We assume that the total size of the market is 100 units, while
the quota volume is only 5 units. Finally, we assume that the elasticity of
substitution among varieties from different sources is 4.
Table 1: Inputs and
Estimated Outcomes in the Armington CES PE Model
|
Policy
Scenario
1
|
Policy
Scenario
2
|
Policy
Scenario
3
|
Model
Inputs
|
|
|
|
Elasticity of Substitution
( )
|
4
|
4
|
4
|
Market Share Subject Imports ( )
|
0.30
|
0.30
|
0.30
|
Market Share Domestic Product ( )
|
0.60
|
0.60
|
0.60
|
Market Share Imports from the Rest of the World ( )
|
0.10
|
0.10
|
0.10
|
In-Quota Tariff Rate on
Subject Imports (
|
0.0
|
0.0
|
0.2
|
Out-of-Quota Tariff Rate on
Subject Imports (
|
0.2
|
0.3
|
0.2
|
Quota Volume ( )
|
5
|
5
|
5
|
Total Market Size ( )
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
|
|
|
|
Estimated
Outcomes
|
|
|
|
Volume of subject imports
under the TRQ
|
16.56
|
12.56
|
16.56
|
Percentage change in the
volume of subject imports
|
-44.80
|
-58.35
|
-44.80
|
Percentage change in the
volume of domestic production
|
14.47
|
19.54
|
14.47
|
In
all three policy scenarios, the TRQ fills (the volume of subject imports under
the TRQ is higher than the quota volume in the TRQ), and the policy reduces the
volume of subject imports while increasing domestic production. The in-quota
rate and the quota volume have no effect on or
, because they do not affect the volume
of subject imports. In this model, the TRQ has the same effect on the volume of
imports and domestic production as a flat tariff rate set at the TRQ’s out-of-quota
rate. This is illustrated by the equivalence of outcomes in the first and third
policy scenarios in Table 1. These two policy scenarios have different
implications for the amount of tariff revenue collected, but they have
identical implications for the volumes of subject imports or domestic
production. In contrast, the higher out-of-quota rate in the second policy scenario
results in a greater reduction in the volume of subject imports and a greater
increase in domestic production.
3.
Krugman
CES Model with Constant Marginal Costs
In the second model, there are different firms from source country . Each firm produces a unique variety. Again,
the model includes three source countries (or groups of countries) that supply
the products of the industry to the domestic market. There are varieties of subject imports, varieties of domestic product, and varieties of imports from the rest of the
world. In this monopolistic competition model, there is entry until profits are
driven to zero, and , and are endogenously determined within the model.
The
price of producer is
a constant mark-up over its constant marginal cost .
(5)
The
industry price index reflects the number of varieties available in the market.
(6)
Equation
(3) is the demand function for the sum of all suppliers
from source country .
(7)
Equation
(4) is the profits that a firm from source country earns
from selling in the domestic market.
(8)
The
variable is
a fixed cost of serving the market from source country , and is
each supplier’s tariff savings at the out-of-quota rate in the TRQ, relative to
its tariff costs if there were a flat tariff at the out-of-quota rate in the TRQ.
Initially, there is no TRQ, and is
equal to zero. and are equal to zero in all of the policy
scenarios. Under the TRQ:
(9)
Equation
(9) assumes that the import quota is allocated equally among the firms that supply subject imports.
Finally,
equation (10) calibrates the preference parameters if the initial prices in the
model are set equal to one.
(10)
The
variable is
the initial number of suppliers from source country . In order to maximize comparability to
the Armington CES model, we assume that .
We
solve for the change in the volume of subject imports and domestic production
due to the TRQ, holding and fixed, by solving for the new equilibrium
number of firms , and based on the zero profit conditions defined by
equations (5), (6), (8) and (9). The model inputs in Table 2 are identical to
the values in Table 1.
Table 2: Inputs and
Estimated Outcomes in the Krugman PE Model
|
Policy
Scenario
1
|
Policy
Scenario
2
|
Policy
Scenario
3
|
Model
Inputs
|
|
|
|
Elasticity of Substitution
( )
|
4
|
4
|
4
|
Market Share Subject Imports ( )
|
0.30
|
0.30
|
0.30
|
Market Share Domestic Product ( )
|
0.60
|
0.60
|
0.60
|
Market Share Imports from the Rest of the World ( )
|
0.10
|
0.10
|
0.10
|
In-Quota Tariff Rate on
Subject Imports (
|
0.0
|
0.0
|
0.2
|
Out-of-Quota Tariff Rate on
Subject Imports (
|
0.2
|
0.3
|
0.2
|
Quota Volume ( )
|
5
|
5
|
5
|
Total Market Size ( )
|
100
|
100
|
100
|
|
|
|
|
Estimated
Outcomes
|
|
|
|
Volume of subject imports
under the TRQ
|
9.70
|
6.87
|
7.84
|
Percentage change in the
volume of subject imports
|
-56.90
|
-69.47
|
-65.14
|
Percentage change in the
volume of domestic production
|
20.69
|
25.85
|
24.93
|
Again
the TRQ fills, the volume of subject imports declines, and domestic production
increases in all three policy scenarios. In this second model, however, there are
adjustments in the number of firms participating in the market, often called
the extensive margin of trade, and larger absolute changes in the volumes of
subject imports and domestic production. Once we incorporate these adjustments
on the extensive margin of trade, there are important new distinctions between
the policy alternatives. In this monopolistic competition model, the in-quota
tariff rate and the quota volume affect or
, because they affect the number of market
participants. A low in-quota rate transfers infra-marginal tariff revenues to
the foreign producers. The TRQ no longer has the same effect on the volume of
imports and domestic production as a flat tariff set at the TRQ’s out-of-quota
rate, so the first and third policy scenarios are no longer equivalent. These
two policy scenarios have different implications for the amount of tariff
revenue collected, but also for the volume of subject imports. The reduction in
the volume of subject imports is much larger for a flat 20 percent tariff than
for the TRQ with an in-quote rate of 0 percent. The increase in the domestic
production is almost as large from raising the in-quota rate from 0 percent to
20 percent (switching from the first policy scenario to the third policy
scenario) as it is from raising the out-of-quota rate from 20 percent to 30
percent while keeping the in-quota rate at 0 percent (switching from the first
policy scenario to the second policy scenario).
4.
Conclusions
and Areas for Future Research
We
have assessed the effects of a TRQ on imports and domestic production using two
different types of partial equilibrium models, an Armington CES model and a
Krugman CES model of trade. In the Armington model with only adjustment on the
intensive margin of trade, a TRQ that fills has the same effect on trade as a
flat tariff at the out-of-quota rate. In the Krugman model, on the other hand, the two policies
are not equivalent and the in-quota rate has an effect on trade and domestic
production even when the TRQ fills.
A
next step would be to consider a Melitz (2003) model of trade with
heterogeneity in the firms’ variable costs of supplying the market. In a Melitz
model, there is adjustment on the extensive margin of trade, so the impact on
subject import volumes and domestic production will depend on all of the parameters
of the TRQ, like in the Krugman model, and not only on the out-of-quota rate.
However, now there is an additional complexity: the impact on subject import
volumes and domestic production will depend on the allocation of the TRQ. It
will depend on whether the duty-free quota volume is available to any importer,
on a first-come-first-served basis, allocated to the more productive firms who
would serve the foreign markets anyway, or allocated to the marginal firms who would
only serve the foreign markets if they can enter duty-free.
References
Armington, Paul S. (1969): “A Theory of Demand for Products Differentiated by
Place of Production.” Staff Papers
(International Monetary Fund) 16(1): 159-78.
Krugman, P.
(1980): “Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade.” American
Economic Review 70(5): 950-959.
Melitz, Marc J.
(2003): “The Impact of Trade on Aggregate Industry Productivity and
Intra-Industry Reallocations.” Econometrica
71: 1695-1725.