ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES
A MULTI-MODE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL
OF TRADE IN PROFESSIONAL SERVICES
Tamar Khachaturian
David Riker
Working
Paper 2016-11-A
U.S.
INTERNATIONAL TRADE COMMISSION
500
E Street SW
Washington,
DC 20436
November 2016
Special
thanks to Zeynep Akgul, Ross Hallren, and Martha Lawless for comments and
assistance with this working paper.
Office of
Economics working papers are the result of ongoing professional research of
USITC Staff and are solely meant to represent the opinions and professional
research of individual authors. These papers are not meant to represent in any
way the views of the U.S. International Trade Commission or any of its
individual Commissioners. Working papers are circulated to promote the active
exchange of ideas between USITC Staff and recognized experts outside the USITC
and to promote professional development of Office Staff by encouraging outside
professional critique of staff research.
A Multi-Mode Partial Equilibrium Model of Trade in
Professional Services
Tamar Khachaturian and David Riker
Office of Economics Working Paper 2016-11-A
November 2016
ABSTRACT
We
develop a partial equilibrium analysis of trade in services based on the theoretical
model with firm heterogeneity and multiple modes of supply in Helpman, Melitz,
and Yeaple (2004). We calibrate the model to the U.S. markets for architectural
and engineering services and legal services, and then we estimate the economic
impact of reducing fixed costs of supplying U.S. markets for these two types of
professional services through cross-border trade and affiliate transactions. For
example, we estimate that 50 percent reductions in the fixed costs of trade in
these professional services would have large effects on the value of
cross-border imports into the U.S. market and on foreign affiliate purchases in
the U.S. market but would have only small effects on the sales of domestic
producers and on overall prices of the services in the U.S. market. The
modeling framework can be easily reapplied to other national markets and other
types of services (or goods) with multiple modes of supply if industry data are
available.
Tamar
Khachaturian
Office
of Industries, Services Division
Tamar.Khachaturian@usitc.gov
David
Riker
Office
of Economics, Research Division
David.Riker@usitc.gov
1.
Introduction
Partial
equilibrium modeling is a popular tool in trade policy analysis. Because of its
relatively narrow focus on particular industries, partial equilibrium analysis
is especially useful for quantifying the economic impact of industry-specific changes
in trade policy. Even
so, partial equilibrium models are rarely used to analyze trade in services. To
address this analytical gap, we develop a set of partial equilibrium models of
trade in services.
Developing an
economic model of trade in services is not simply a matter of reapplying the
standard partial equilibrium framework to a new set of products, because there
are distinctive characteristics of trade in services that need to be built into
the model. First, the international provision of services occurs through several
alternative modes of supply, captured in trade statistics such as cross-border trade
and foreign affiliate transactions.
Second, there are often significant fixed costs of entering different national
markets. Third, the services of each provider are usually highly differentiated
products. And, finally, although there are no tariffs or freight charges on
cross-border trade in services, there can be significant non-tariff barriers to
trade.
The Helpman,
Melitz, and Yeaple (HMY) model of cross-border trade and horizontal foreign direct
investment is well-suited for analyzing trade liberalization in services
industries.
The model includes heterogeneity in the productivity of service providers from
each country, alternative modes for supplying foreign markets, and fixed costs
that are barriers to each mode of supply. Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple derive
closed-form solutions for the values of cross-border exports and foreign
affiliate sales, based on specific functional forms that represent consumer
preferences, trade costs, and the distribution of productivity levels across
individual firms. There is a large literature that empirically tests and
generally supports the
predictions of the HMY model, including Girma, Kneller, and Pisu (2005) for
U.K. firms, Tomiura (2007) for Japanese firms, Yeaple (2008) for U.S. firms,
and Engel and Procher (2012) for French firms.
In this
paper, we use a partial equilibrium version of the HMY model to simulate the
impact of trade liberalization in two professional services industries that supply
services in foreign markets through multiple modes of delivery: architectural
and engineering services and legal services. In our specific applications, we
estimate the effect of reducing fixed costs of exporting into the United States
and the
incremental fixed costs of foreign affiliate provision of two categories of
professional services in the United States. We estimate that 50 percent reductions
in the fixed costs of trade in these professional services would have large
effects on the value of cross-border imports into the U.S. market and on
foreign affiliate purchases in the U.S. market, but would have only small
effects on the sales of domestic producers and on overall prices of the
services in the U.S. market. Holding the incremental fixed costs of foreign
affiliate provision constant,
a 50 percent reduction in the fixed costs
of exporting into the U.S. market would
increase cross-border imports by approximately 52 percent (architectural and
engineering services) and 28 percent (legal services), and would reduce average
prices prevailing in the respective industries by 0.19 and 0.04 percent. Holding
the fixed costs of exporting into the
United States constant, we
estimate that a 50 percent reduction in the
incremental fixed costs of foreign affiliate provision would increase foreign affiliate purchases in
the U.S. by 26 percent (architectural and engineering services) and 28 percent
(legal services), and would reduce average prices prevailing in the respective
industries by 0.18 and .007 percent.
The
contribution of this paper is that it demonstrates a practical way to quantify
the impact of reducing barriers to trade in two professional services industries,
using a partial equilibrium version of the HMY model. The estimation utilizes
data on all of the different modes of service provision within an integrated
modeling framework. The model’s modest data requirements also accommodate the
limitations in available data on services.
The rest of
the paper is organized into six sections. Section 2 provides an overview of the
international supply of the two types of professional services. Section 3 summarizes
the HMY model. Section 4 discusses the data that we use to calibrate the parameters
of the models to the U.S. market. Section 5 reports estimates of the impact of
a 50 percent reduction in fixed costs associated with international trade in
architectural and engineering services. Section 6 reports estimates of the
impact of a 50 percent reduction in fixed costs associated with trade in legal
services. Section 7 draws conclusions and recommends directions for future
research.
2.
Trade
in Architectural and Engineering Services and Legal Services
The economic
models in this paper focus on U.S. inbound trade in professional services.
The models are based on information from the International Services database of the U.S. Bureau of Economic
Analysis (BEA) on U.S. foreign affiliate transactions and cross-border trade in
2012, by category of service and by partner country, and data from the 2012 Economic Census on total U.S. revenues
of service providers in the United States, by category of service.
Table 1 summarizes these data for 2012.
In addition
to this information on trade and foreign affiliate sales of architectural and
engineering services and legal services, there is considerable evidence that
there are barriers to the foreign provision of these services, in the U.S.
market and abroad, as described below based on the OECD
Services Trade Restrictiveness Index (STRI).
We expect that partial or complete elimination of these barriers will have
economically significant effects on both modes of supply.
2.A. Architectural and Engineering Services
Architects and engineers provide
services related to the construction and design of buildings and other
infrastructure, as well as the design of industrial procedures and production
processes. In foreign markets, these services are supplied through multiple
modes of delivery.
Due to technological advances, cross-border supply (or mode 1 supply), and
specifically the digital delivery of services, for example, supplying
architectural designs or engineering plans abroad via e-mail) is a growing area
of trade, with U.S. cross-border exports and imports of architectural and
engineering services experiencing 8.7 and 10 percent average yearly growth from
2006-2014, respectively.
Cross-border supply is often complemented by trade in the form of “movement of
person” or mode 4 trade, when architects and engineers travel to provide
services in foreign markets. For example, architectural designs provided
through cross-border delivery might also warrant the architect visiting the project
site to implement and manage the project. Finally, mode 3 trade, the supply of architectural
and engineering services through the establishment of a commercial presence
(e.g., a foreign affiliate), is an alternative and possibly complementary mode of
supply, allowing companies to provide services throughout various phases of
projects in host countries. Architectural and engineering services supplied by U.S.-owned foreign
affiliates (foreign affiliate sales) grew by 14.7 percent between 2006 and 2012, while purchases from U.S. affiliates of foreign firms (U.S.
affiliate purchases) grew by 6.1 percent between 2006 and 2013.
In 2012, the year of the data used in the model calibration, foreign affiliate
sales ($35.8 billion) were more than double cross-border exports ($13.4
billion) and U.S. affiliate purchases ($12.9 billion) far exceeded cross-border
imports ($4.8 billion).
Although policies related to the
foreign provision of architectural and engineering services tend to be less
restrictive than in other areas of professional services, countries maintain
regulations related to the entry or operation of foreign or foreign-owned service
providers that likely impede trade, including most notably discriminatory
qualification and licensing requirements. The OECD STRI for architectural and
engineering services categorizes trade restrictions into five groups:
restrictions on foreign entry, restrictions to movement of people, barriers to
competition, other discriminatory measures, and regulatory transparency.
In architectural and engineering services, the most prevalent are restrictions
to movement of people (this category affects either all modes of trade or
specifically mode 4 trade) and restrictions on foreign entry (this category
affects mode 3 trade). In the former category, quotas and labor market tests for example work permits that depend on
proving that the vacancy could not be filled by a local employee or that the
work by the foreign employee will benefit the local economy are
prevalent and restrict or limit foreign architects and engineers from traveling
to host countries on a temporary basis. Also in this category, restrictions on
recognition of foreign qualifications (for example, local practice or
examination requirements) and licensing (residency and in a few cases,
nationality requirements) are prevalent and affect all modes of trade. Restrictions
that affect the entry of foreign firms include specific requirements on the
composition of boards of directors or the management of engineering and
architecture firms (such as residency), restrictions on acquiring land (which
affects construction services directly and the architectural and engineering services
indirectly), and in some cases foreign equity restrictions for non-locally licensed
architects. The remaining restrictions affect the use of professional titles (e.g.,
titles of “architect” or “engineer”), prices, and advertising architectural services.
Table 2 summarizes the most restrictive
measures that apply to select countries with above average architectural and
engineering services STRI scores, as well as the United States. For example,
Poland restricts allowable legal forms for architecture and engineering firms,
conditions employment and residency permits on either proving positive local
impacts or that the vacancy could not be filled locally, and maintains that
providers of architectural and engineering services must be members of national
associations that, in turn, require EU citizenship. The STRI scores for the
United States are much lower than their counterparts in the other countries,
and this suggests fewer or less intense restrictions on trade in these
services.
2.B. Legal Services
International
trade in legal services typically involve foreign lawyers providing legal
services in their home country law, international law, or third country law. Host
country law is normally subject to local requalification or restricted from
trade. However, with the growing significance of foreign affiliates of law
firms established abroad and supplying multi-jurisdictional advice to their
local clients’ international business dealings, providing host country law is
an increasingly important area of international trade.
It is reported that supplying services via the establishment of a commercial
presence (mode 3) and via the movement of people (mode 4) are the preferred
modes of delivery in foreign markets.
In 2012, U.S. cross-border exports ($8.3 billion)
exceeded foreign affiliate sales ($5.1
billion) of legal services and cross-border imports ($2 billion)
exceeded U.S. affiliate purchases ($0.13 billion) of legal services. Cross-border imports have also grown at a faster average
annual rate than U.S. affiliate purchases (7.7 percent from 2006 to 2014
versus 1.8 percent from 2006 to 2013). However,
foreign affiliate sales have grown at a faster average annual rate than
cross-border exports of legal services in recent years (11.9 percent
from 2006 to 2013 versus 7.4 percent from 2006 to 2014).
Policies
related to the foreign provision of legal services tend to be the most
restrictive among professional services.
The STRI for legal services is categorized into the same five groups as architectural
and engineering services. Also like architectural and engineering services, the
most prevalent are restrictions to movement of people and restrictions on
foreign entry. Notably, in the former category, nationality and/or residency
requirements to practice law, along with lack of recognition of foreign
qualifications, are significant impediments and affect all modes of trade.
In this same category, quotas and labor market tests are also prevalent and
restrict or limit foreign attorneys from traveling to host countries on a
temporary basis. When applicable, the category of restrictions affecting
foreign entry differentiates between firms practicing international versus
domestic law. For example, countries commonly restrict ownership of law firms
to locally-qualified lawyers only in domestic law practice. Other prevalent
restrictions in this category include local qualifications for a majority of
the board of directors/equity partners/managers and limits on commercial
association between locally and non-locally licensed attorneys.
Restrictions in other categories relate to fee-setting and advertising.
Table 3
presents the most restrictive measures that apply
to select countries with above average legal services STRI scores, as well as
the United States. In the two cases where trade is completely restricted,
nationality or residency restrictions apply to either or both domestic and
international law practice and a temporary licensing system is not in place. In
India, which has one of the most restrictive scores, legal services can only be
provided by Indian citizens. Foreign law firms are not permitted to establish
businesses and non-locally licensed attorneys cannot invest in law firms in
India. Additionally, Indian law firms cannot commercially associate or partner
with non-locally licensed attorneys and foreign law firms cannot hire local
attorneys for the purpose of providing host country legal advice. Again, the
STRI score for the United States is much lower than for counterparts in the
other countries, and this suggests fewer or less intense restrictions on trade
in these services.
3.
HMY
Framework
In this
section, we derive an economic model of foreign affiliate sales and cross-border
exports of services, based on a partial equilibrium version of the HMY framework.
Then we derive formulas for calculating the impact of reducing the fixed costs
of trade in these services.
Each of the partial
equilibrium models is narrowly focused on a single category of services. Labor
is the only factor of production and,
following Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004), we assume that the wages in each
country are equalized by international trade in other sectors of the economy,
and to simplify the notation, we set these wages equal to one in all countries.
Providers of the services vary in their
productivity. There are firms
headquartered in each country , and the unit labor requirement of each
firm, , is drawn from a distribution with cumulative
distribution function . The
firms provide services that are differentiated from the services provided by
other firms within their category, and they engage in monopolistic competition.
The parameter is the
constant elasticity of substitution between different varieties of services
within the category.
The
HMY model includes three costs of serving a foreign market. The first is a
variable cost of cross-border exports from country to
country , , that has an iceberg form. This is an ad valorem trade cost that
increases the marginal cost of supplying market across the border by percent. The
second is a fixed cost of exporting from country to
country , equal to units of labor. The third is a fixed cost
incurred when a firm from country establishes a foreign affiliate in country . Following Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004), we
represent this third cost in terms of the incremental
fixed cost of foreign affiliate sales relative to cross-border exports.
This incremental fixed cost is equal to units of labor. The model also includes fixed
costs of producing in country to
supply the domestic market, equal to units of labor.
Equation
(1) represents the profits of a firm with unit labor requirement in
country from
serving its domestic market.
(1)
Following
the notation in Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004), represents the aggregate expenditure level in
country , is the
constant expenditure share of the services category, and is a
CES price index for the services category in country .
Equation
(2) is the profits of a firm in country from
exporting its service to country .
(2)
Equation (3)
is the incremental profits of a country firm
that serves the market in country through foreign affiliate sales rather than
cross-border exports.
(3)
A firm’s
most profitable mode of supply depends on the firm’s unit labor requirement. All
firms in country with
unit labor requirements below sell
in their domestic market. The cutoff
level for domestic sales is implicitly defined in equation (4).
(4)
In
addition, firms in country with unit labor requirements below a cutoff level also
supply the foreign market, either through cross-border exports or through
foreign affiliate sales. Firms from country with unit labor requirements below the cutoff serve
country by
establishing a foreign affiliate in the country. Firms in country with unit labor requirements below a cutoff level but
above serve
country through cross-border exports. In the HMY
model, firms do not engage in both exporting and foreign affiliate sales in the
same market, and all firms that participate in foreign markets also produce for
their domestic market.
These cutoff
levels are implicitly defined by the condition for zero profits in cross-border
exports (in equation (5)) and for zero incremental profits for foreign
affiliate sales relative to cross-border exports (in equation (6)).
(5)
(6)
According to
Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004), . The most productive firms establish foreign
affiliates, while the least productive firms only serve their domestic market.
Equations
(1) through (6) imply that the relative cutoff levels are determined by all four
types of costs.
(7)
(8)
We
assume that the magnitudes of the different types of fixed costs ensure that .
Equations
(9), (10), and (11) represent the equilibrium value of foreign affiliate sales
( ),
cross-border exports ( ), and
domestic shipments ( ) that
are associated with the cutoff unit labor requirements defined by equations (4),
(5) and (6).
(9)
(10)
(11)
Equation
(12) is the country CES
price index for the category of services.
(12)
The
variable in
equation (12) is an index of all countries other than .
If the
productivity of individual firms has a Pareto distribution with shape parameter
, as in Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004),
then
for a
lower boundary and an
upper boundary . In this case, we can rewrite equations (9)
through (12) in terms of the cutoff levels , , and .
(13)
(14)
(15)
(16)
We can
further rewrite equations (13) through (16) in terms of the relative cutoff
levels and .
(17)
(18)
(19)
To
simplify the notation in equations (17) through (19), we defined the common
term
(20)
Finally,
we can substitute equations (7) through (8) into equations (17), (18), and
(20).
(21)
(22)
(23)
Finally,
we calculate the impact of reducing the two types of fixed costs of trade on
foreign affiliate sales, cross-border exports, domestic sales, and prices in country
by
totally differentiating the equations of the model.The notation represents the proportional change in variable
.
(24)
(25)
(26)
(27)
In
equation (27), and are
the market shares for cross-border imports and foreign affiliates purchases in
the market. Assuming that
(28)
(29)
(30)
Equations
(28) through (30) indicate that the reductions in the two types of fixed costs
affect market outcome through adjustments on extensive margins. There is no adjustment on the intensive
margins, because wages and variable trade costs remain constant in the partial
equilibrium framework. The
participation of domestic firms, domestic affiliates of foreign firms, and
exports of foreign firms on the market adjusts to reductions in fixed costs,
including induced adjustments in the price index for the market.
When either of the types of fixed costs decline, there is an increase in the
number of foreign firms participating in the market and a reduction in the
number of domestic firms. Since the new entrants are more productive than the
firms that exit, the price index for the market declines.
These equations
provide estimates of the effects of reductions in and on
foreign affiliate purchases, cross-border imports, domestic sales, and prices
in the U.S. market. The equations utilize data on the market shares of imports to
the U.S. market and foreign affiliate purchases in the U.S. market, as well as
the shape parameter of the distribution of productivities, the elasticity of
substitution among varieties, the relative magnitude of the two types of fixed
costs, and the magnitude of the variable trade costs.
4.
Calibration
of the Parameters of the PE Model
Table 4 reports
the market shares for cross-border imports and foreign affiliate purchases in
the U.S. market, and . The denominator for these share
calculations, total consumption of services in the U.S. market, is calculated
as the sum of total revenue of service providers in the United States, from the
2012 Economic Census, minus
cross-border exports from the United States plus cross-border imports into the
United States, from the BEA data in Table 1.
Zhai (2008)
estimates that (the elasticity of substitution) for all services
is equal to 4.3, based on evidence that
mark-up ratios in these industries are approximately 30 percent. Di Giovanni,
Levchenko, and Rancière (2011) estimate that is
equal 1.155 in professional services industries, based on a large sample of
non-exporting French firms. Together, these estimates from the literature imply
the (the
shape parameter in the Pareto distribution of productivities) is equal to
5.1315 = 1.155 * (4.3-1).
Next, we
calibrate for
the U.S. market using the equations of the model. Equation (31) is implied by
equations (21) and (22).
(31)
Inverting
equation (31),
(32)
Finally,
we estimate the effects of the reductions in fixed costs for several different values
of variable trade costs parameter, , ranging from 1.1 to 1.3.
5.
Estimated
Impact on Trade in Architectural and Engineering Services
First, we
estimate the effects of reducing fixed costs of exporting to the United States (a
reduction in ) and the incremental fixed costs of foreign
affiliate provision in the United States (a reduction in ) on
international trade in architectural and engineering services. Table 5 reports
that a 50 percent reduction in (holding
fixed)
would increase cross-border imports into the United States by approximately 52
percent. It would reduce the price index
for the services category by approximately 0.19 percent. This would benefit
consumers in the United States but would also reduce the demand for services
supplied through the other modes of supply. Domestic sales and foreign
affiliates purchases in the United States would both decline by approximately 1
percent.
Separately,
Table 5 reports that a 50 percent reduction in (holding
fixed)
would increase foreign affiliate purchases of the services in the United States
by 26 percent. It would reduce the price index
for the services category by approximately 0.18 percent. This would benefit
consumers in the United States but would also reduce the demand for services
supplied through the other modes. Domestic sales in the United States would decline
by approximately 1 percent, and cross-border imports would decline by
approximately 26 percent.
The effects
of simultaneously reducing both types of fixed costs is simply the sum (or net)
of the effects in the two columns for each row in Table 5, because the estimated
impacts are based on linear equations (24) through (30). In this case, there would
be a net increase in foreign affiliate purchases and cross-border imports and a
net decrease in domestic sales and the price index for the range of values of that
we considered.
6.
Estimated
Impact on Trade in Legal Services
Finally, we estimate
the effects of reducing fixed costs of exporting to the United States (a
reduction in ) and the incremental fixed costs of foreign
affiliate provision in the United States (a reduction in ) on
international trade in legal services. Table 6 reports that a 50 percent
reduction in (holding fixed)
would increase cross-border imports into the United States by approximately 28
percent. It would reduce the price index
for the services category by approximately 0.04 percent. This would benefit
consumers in the United States but would also reduce the demand for services
supplied through the other modes. Domestic sales and foreign affiliate purchases
in the United States would both decline by 0.23 percent.
Separately,
Table 6 reports that a 50 percent reduction in (holding fixed)
would increase foreign affiliate purchases of the services in the United States
by approximately 28 percent. It will
reduce the price index for the services category by approximately 0.001 percent.
This would benefit consumers in the United States but would also reduce the
demand for services supplied through the other modes. Domestic sales in the
United States would decline by approximately 0.007 percent, and cross-border
imports would decline by approximately 0.8 percent. The smaller effects in
table 6 reflect the very small share of foreign affiliate purchases and
cross-border imports into the U.S. market for legal services, as reported in
table 4. In fact, all of the differences in the estimates in table 6, relative
to table 5, are due to the differences in these market shares.
7.
Conclusions
This paper
extends conventional partial equilibrium models used in trade policy analysis
to address trade in services, rather than trade in goods, and to incorporate
alternative modes of supplying services to foreign markets. The HMY model
provides an excellent framework for this analysis, with its tractable equations
and reasonable data requirements.
In our
specific applications we estimate the effect of reducing fixed costs of exporting
into the United States (a reduction in ) and the incremental fixed costs of foreign
affiliate provision (a reduction in ) to two
categories of professional services in the United States. Holding fixed,
a 50 percent reduction in would increase cross-border imports by approximately
52 percent (architectural and engineering services) and 28 percent (legal
services) and would reduce prices in the respective industries by 0.19 and 0.04
percent. We estimate that a 50 percent reduction in ,
holding fixed,
would increase foreign affiliate purchases in the U.S. by 26 percent
(architectural and engineering services) and 28 percent (legal services) and would
reduce prices in the respective industries by 0.18 and .007 percent.
These models
quantify the economic impact of hypothetical reductions in the fixed costs of
trade, but the models do not provide a method for estimating the magnitude of cost reductions associated
with specific policy changes. To provide an illustration of how the model
works, we have assumed 50 percent reductions in one or both of the types of
fixed costs. The relevant magnitudes of these “shocks” to the models are
critical inputs into an analysis of actual policy changes and are therefore a
very important area for future research.
Finally, our
review of OECD STRIs in tables 2 and 3 suggest that there may be even larger
potential gains from liberalizing markets for services in other countries,
though the challenge for future research will be collecting reliable data on
markets shares and in
these markets.
References
Borchert, Ingo, Batshur Gootiiz,
and Aaditya Mattoo (2014): “Policy Barriers to International Trade in Services:
Evidence from a New Database.” World Bank
Economic Review 28: 162-188.
Di Giovanni, Julian, Andrei A.
Levchenko, and Romain Rancière (2011): “Power Laws in Firm Size and Openness to
Trade: Measurement and Implications.” Journal
of International Economics 85: 42-52.
Engel, Dirk and Vivien Procher
(2012): “Export, FDI and Firm Productivity.” Applied Economics 44: 1931-1340.
Francois, Joseph and Bernard
Hoekman (2010): “Services Trade and Policy.” Journal of Economic Literature 48: 642-692.
Girma, Sourafel, Richard Kneller,
and Mauro Pisu (2005): “Exports versus FDI: An Empirical Test.” Review of World
Economics/WeltwirtschaftlichesArchiv 141(2): 193-218.
Grimm, Alexis N. and Charu S.
Krishnan (2014): “International Services: Trade in Services in 2013 and
Services Supplied through Affiliates in 2012.” Survey of Current Business, October, 1-25.
Grosso, Geloso M., et al. (2014): "Services Trade
Restrictiveness Index (STRI): Construction, Architecture and Engineering
Services." OECD Trade Policy Papers, No. 170,
OECD Publishing, Paris.
Grosso, Geloso M., et al. (2014): "Services Trade
Restrictiveness Index (STRI): Legal and Accounting Services". OECD Trade Policy Papers, No. 171,
OECD Publishing, Paris.
Helpman, Elhanan, Marc J. Melitz,
and Stephen R. Yeaple (2004): “Export Versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms.” American Economic Review 94(1): 300-316.
Koncz, Jennifer, Michaell Mann,
and Erin Nephew (2006): “U.S. International Services: Cross-Border Trade in
2005 and Sales Through Affilates in 2004.” Survey
of Current Business, October, 18-74.
Markusen, James (2002): Multinational Firms and the Theory of
International Trade. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.
Melitz, Marc J. (2003): “The
Impact of Trade on Aggregate Industry Productivity and Intra-Industry
Reallocations.” Econometrica 71:
1695-1725.
OECD (2016): “STRI Sector Brief:
Legal Services.”
Riker, David (2015): “The Impact of
Restrictions on Mode 3 International Supply of Services.” Journal of International and Global Economic Studies 8(1): 1-20.
Tomiura, Eiichi. (2007): “Foreign
Outsourcing, Exporting, and FDI: A Productivity Comparison at the Firm Level.” Journal of International Economics 72:
113-127.
Yeaple, Stephen R. (2009): “Firm
Heterogeneity and the Structure of U.S. Multinational Activity.” Journal of International Economics 78:
206-215.
Van der Marel, Erik and Ben
Shepherd (2013): “Services Trade, Regulation and Regional Integration: Evidence
from Sectoral Data.” World Economy
36: 1393-1405.
Zhai, Fan (2008): “Armington
Meets Melitz: Introducing Firm Heterogeneity in a Global CGE Model of Trade.” Journal of Economic Integration 23(3):
575-604.
Table 1: U.S. Trade in Certain Professional
Services in 2012 (in billions of US dollars)
Category of
Services
|
Cross-Border Exports
|
Cross-Border Imports
|
Outbound
FAS
|
Inbound
FAS
|
Architectural and Engineering
Services
|
13.411
|
4.807
|
35.780
|
12.874
|
Legal Services
|
8.280
|
2.033
|
5.125
|
0.134
|
Source:
BEA International Services Database.
Table 2: Architectural and Engineering
Services Restrictions for Selected Countries
Country
and Score
|
Restrictions
on
Foreign Entry
|
Restrictions
on Movement of People
|
Other
|
India
Architecture: 0.626, Engineering: 0.273
|
Equity
restrictions applying to non-locally licensed individuals or firms
(architecture); legal form; residency (engineering) and nationality/licensing
(architecture) for board of directors; acquisition and use of land and real
estate by foreigners; repatriation of capital; mergers and acquisitions
|
Labor
market tests; limitations on stay; employment visa related requirements
(engineering); nationality or citizenship required for license to practice
(architecture)
|
Fee
setting (architecture); advertising (architecture); minimum capital
requirements
|
Poland
Architecture: 0.435, Engineering: 0.427
|
Legal
form; acquisition and use of land and real estate by foreigners
|
Labor
market tests; limitations on stay;
nationality or citizenship requirements for license to practice
|
Fee
setting (architecture); minimum capital requirements
|
Slovak
Republic
Architecture:
0.471, Engineering: 0.484
|
Equity
restrictions applying to non-locally licensed individuals or firms; licensing
for board of directors; residency for management
|
Labor
market tests; limitations on stay; nationality or citizenship requirements
for license to practice
|
Fee
setting (engineering); minimum capital requirements; advertising
|
United
States Architecture:
0.15, Engineering: 0.18
|
Foreign
investment screening
|
Quotas
(contractual/independent service suppliers); local exam and practice
requirements; permanent residency/domicile required for practice
(engineering)
|
|
Source:
OECD Services Trade Restrictiveness Index Simulator (accessed September 21,
2016). https://sim.oecd.org/default.ashx.
Note: Most restrictive policies in the "Foreign Entry" and
"Movement of People" categories are listed (i.e. excluding those
which may be scored greater than 0 but are subsumed by a binding restriction).
Select restrictions in the remaining categories are listed. The average STRI
score in architecture is 0.23 and in engineering is 0.20.
Table 3: Legal Services Restrictions for
Selected Countries
Country and Score
|
Restrictions on
Foreign Entry
|
Restrictions on Movement of People
|
Other
|
India
Legal:
0.946
|
No foreign
equity in law firms and restrictions on ownership by non- locally licensed
attorneys (both domestic and international); prohibitions on commercial
association and hiring local lawyers
|
Labor
market tests; limitations on stay; Citizenship required for practice (both
domestic and international law)
|
Advertising
prohibited (non- discriminatory)
|
Korea
Legal:
0.475
|
Restrictions
on ownership by lawyers (Korean law firms, domestic law); certain commercial
association restrictions; board of directors and managers must be lawyers in
Korean law firms (domestic law); local office for foreign legal consultants;
repatriation of profits
|
Limitation
on stay; residency for foreign legal consultants; domicile requirement for
domestic and international law; education and practice requirements for
domestic law; lack of temporary licensing
|
|
Poland
Legal:
1.000
|
Restrictions
on ownership by non-locally licensed attorneys (both domestic and
international); legal form; certain restrictions on commercial association;
board of directors and managers must be licensed lawyers; establishment requirements
for host country law
|
Labor
markets tests; limitations on stay; domicile requirements for host country
law; recognition of foreign qualifications based on reciprocity
(international law) and/or education/practice in Poland (domestic law); lack
of temporary licensing
|
Advertising
restrictions; minimum capital requirements
|
United
States Legal: 0.16
|
Licensing
requirements for board of directors and managers (domestic law); foreign
investment screening; local office requirements for nonresident attorneys
|
Quotas
(contractual/independent service suppliers); local exam requirements
(domestic law); lack of temporary licensing
|
|
Source:
OECD Services Trade Restrictiveness Index Simulator (accessed September 21,
2016). https://sim.oecd.org/default.ashx.
Note: Most restrictive policies in the "Foreign Entry" and
"Movement of People" categories are listed (i.e. excluding those
which may be scored greater than 0 but are subsumed by a binding restriction);
in the case of India, many scored measures are not listed as they are not
applicable since foreign law firms are not permitted to establish in India.
Select restrictions in the remaining categories are listed. The average STRI
score in legal services is 0.36.
Table 4: Market Shares in the U.S. Market in
2012 (percent)
Category
of
Services
|
Share of
Cross-Border Imports
|
Share of
Inbound FAS
|
Architectural and Engineering Services
|
1.87
|
5.00
|
Legal Services
|
0.80
|
0.05
|
Source:
BEA International Services Database.
Table 5: Estimated Impact on Trade in Architectural and Engineering Services
Economic Outcome
(in
percent changes)
|
Variable
Trade Cost
|
50 Percent
Reduction in
|
50 Percent
Reduction in
|
Foreign Affiliate Sales in the United
States
|
1.1
1.2
1.3
|
-0.9951
-1.0145
-0.9656
|
26.8387
26.8581
26.8092
|
Cross-Border Imports into the United States
|
1.1
1.2
1.3
|
52.2175
53.2382
50.6730
|
-26.3739
-27.3946
-24.8294
|
Domestic Sales in the U.S. Market
|
1.1
1.2
1.3
|
-0.9951
-1.0145
-0.9656
|
-0.9113
-0.8919
-0.9408
|
Price Index in the U.S. Market
|
1.1
1.2
1.3
|
-0.1939
-0.1977
-0.1882
|
-0.1776
-0.1738
-0.1833
|
Table 6: Estimated Impact on Trade in Legal
Services
Economic
Outcome
(in
percent changes)
|
Variable
Trade Cost
|
50 Percent
Reduction in
|
50 Percent
Reduction in
|
Foreign Affiliate Sales in the United
States
|
1.1
1.2
1.3
|
-0.2292
-0.2282
-0.2271
|
27.7434
27.7423
27.7412
|
Cross-Border Imports into the United States
|
1.1
1.2
1.3
|
28.4257
28.2981
28.1584
|
-0.9116
-0.7840
-0.6443
|
Domestic Sales in the U.S. Market
|
1.1
1.2
1.3
|
-0.2292
-0.2282
-0.2271
|
-0.0066
-0.0077
-0.0088
|
Price Index in the U.S. Market
|
1.1
1.2
1.3
|
-0.0447
-0.0445
-0.0443
|
-0.0013
-0.0015
-0.0017
|